Building a resilient economy
Analysing options for systemic change
to transform the world’s economic and
nancial systems after the pandemic.
Building
a resilient
economy
institute fo
r
future-fit
economies
Page intentionally left blank.
Page intentionally left blank.
Project Consortium
ZOE-Institute for future-t economies, Germany
New Economics Foundation, United Kingdom
Wellbeing Economy Alliance, United Kingdom
The project was led by ZOE-Institute for future-t economies (ZOE) in close
cooperation with the New Economics Foundation (NEF) and the Wellbeing Economy
Alliance (WEAll).
Please cite as:
Barth J. and Coscieme L., Dimmelmeier, A., Kumar C., Mewes S., Nuesse I., Pendleton
A., Trebeck K. (2020): Analysing options for systemic change to transform the world’s
economic and nancial systems. ZOE-Institute for future-t economies: Bonn.
Transparency
This paper is based on a review commissioned by the WWF.
The nancial support of Partners for a New Economy (P4NE) is greatly appreciated.
ISSN: 2627-9436
Acknowledgements
We would like to thank all people who supported us in the development of this report.
First and foremost, the WWF team, who developed the initial study concept and
provided advice and expertise throughout (Toby Roxburgh, Karen Ellis, Ray Dhirani,
Angela Francis, Dominic White, Stefano Esposito). We would also like to thank the
participants of the survey and the webinar where we presented a preliminary version
of the report. Thanks also to all those who assisted us in the background during the
development. These include Lisa Boll, Olivia Davis, Anais Gradinger, Christoph Gran,
Elias Huland, Benedikt Hummel and Lukas Salecker.
Layout and design concept
Drees + Riggers
Photos
Cover: Juliane Liebermann, p. 19: Myles Tan, p. 20 / 21: Adrian Infernus, p. 46 / 47:
Cagatay Orhan, p. 53: Julia Stepper (all photos taken from unsplash.com)
Copyright
© ZOE-Institute for future-t economies, 2020
The views expressed in this document are those of the authors. This publication and
its contents may be reproduced as long as the reference source is cited.
Contact details
Jonathan Barth,
Institute for future-t economies gUG (haftungsbeschränkt),
jonathan.barth@zoe-institut.de
Content
Executive Summary 8
Introduction 11
Background: The economics of biodiversity
and the need for systemic change 13
Addressing biodiversity loss 13
Understanding and dening systemic change 15
Methodology 17
Part 1: Overview of barriers and
policy proposals for changing the
economic and nancial system
20
Policy and governance 24
Barriers to policy change 24
Options for systemic change 25
Finance 28
Barriers to a sustainable transformation
of the nancial system 29
The role of policy in setting nance on
course for tackling today's challenges 30
Business 33
Barriers to implementing sustainable
and fair business models 33
Policy options to drive sustainable business behaviour 34
Citizens 36
Barriers for change towards sustainable
living and drivers for unsustainable behaviour 36
Policy actions to enable sustainable living 37
Interim conclusion: thinking about and
engaging in systemic change 40
Part 2: Policy options for the UK
to move towards a resilient economy
46
Rationale behind this prioritisation 50
1. A Wellbeing Budget for the UK 54
2. Modernising UK’s Fiscal Rules 58
3. A New National Investment Authority 61
4. Mandatory Financial Risk Assessments and Disclosure 64
5. Green Credit Guidance 68
6. Land Value Tax 71
7. Resource Caps and Biodiversity 74
8. Environmental Border Tax 78
Interim conclusion: The interplay of policy proposals 82
In place of a conclusion: A story of hope 86
Endnotes 88
Appendix 112
8
Executive SummaryBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Executive Summary
In 2020, the world’s governments acted at an
impressive scale and speed to mobilise resources
in response to COVID-19. By April, they had col-
lectively assigned US $ 9 trillion to buffer against
the economic impacts of the pandemic. In the UK
alone, 176.7 billion were made available as an
immediate scal response.
As these eye-watering sums illustrate (and
those associated with the banking crash in 2008
reinforce), dealing with a crisis is very cost-
ly, in economic terms as well as regarding social
impacts. Therefore, where a crisis is foreseeable
as in the case of climate change and increasing bio-
diversity loss, societies should invest in preventa-
tive measures.
Science shows us that humanity’s impacts
on the planet are intensifying and environmen-
tal trends are heading in the wrong direction. In
response, there have been calls for systemic
interventions from prominent international agen-
cies including the United Nations Environment Pro-
gramme, the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate
Change (IPCC) and the Intergovernmental Sci-
ence-Policy Platform on Biodiversity and Ecosys-
tem Services (IPBES).
These agencies recommend a rapid transition
towards an economy thats low-carbon, resource-
light and that restores nature. They are promot-
ing the need for a fundamental reform of our eco-
nomic systems, so that equality, environment, and
wellbeing become core to the way our economies
function. Its an agenda that has been endorsed
by mainstream actors such as the World Econom-
ic Forum, the Financial Times and the Economist.
Many reports, ideas and proposals make the
case for the required changes. What has been
missing is a better understanding of how system-
ic change can be put into operation and, given the
urgency and interdependency of the issue, how the
UK can effectively support a fundamental trans-
formation of its economic system towards a resil-
ient economy.
This report it is an attempt to ll this gap. The follow-
ing chapters (and the research underpinning them)
focus on the role of government and policy in deliver
-
ing systemic change. We outline where public policy-
makers should place the emphasis in order to trans-
form the world’s economic and nancial systems most
effectively to mitigate future environmental crises.
The report proposes a set of policies the UK
government could implement to amplify impact
and ensure long-term systemic change both for
its domestic economy and at an international level.
There is no “silver bulletsolution to the multiple
crises we face, and many changes will be required,
involving governments, investors, businesses and
the public alike so the policy package we out-
line is a blueprint to deliver systemic change in
the current policy context. It should be regarded
as a basis for discussion to demonstrate the scale,
nature and interlinkages of the changes required.
We start by categorising the key areas for sys-
temic intervention that can shift behaviour in the
longer term into four sections (policy, nance,
business, and citizens), as illustrated in Table 1.
The rst part of our report provides a summa-
ry of almost 300 transformative proposals split
into these four categories. Each proposal has the
potential to address the socioeconomic root caus-
es of todays crises through policy changes that
have cross-cutting and transformative impact.
Building on this comprehensive list of propos-
als we set three key criteria to identify the most
promising policies:
1. Relevance: their relevance and topicality in
the UK context.
2. COVID-19 suitability: the extent to which
they could support a sustainable economic
recovery from COVID-19.
3. Transformative potential: the impact they
have on driving long-term systemic change.
Policy Finance Business Citizens
Multidimensional
indicators, moni-
toring capacity, and legal
frameworks: ensure
political decision making
addresses the environ-
ment and wellbeing with
equal weight on the
economic aspects.
Fiscal policy and
growth independ-
ence: increase the space
for scal interventions to
support a green and just
transition and decouple
economic stability from
economic growth.
Limiting power
and empowerment
for change: reduce
economic and democratic
power imbalances.
Mandates and legal
interpretations:
include environmental
and social objectives in
the targets of public insti-
tutions such as central
banks and development
banks.
Metrics for the
long-term: integrate
environmental categories
and extend the time hori-
zon in risk assessments.
Shifting
Protability:
internalise the costs of
environmental damage.
Sustainable invest-
ment and innova-
tion: shift investment and
techno logy from resource-
intensive activities to
those that are less resource-
intensive but more
labour-intensive.
Non-nancial
disclosure, report-
ing and accountability:
include environmental
objectives in business
reporting standards.
Sustainable
business models:
Support business models
that focus on sustainabil-
ity and well being and
create a level playing
eld.
Sustainable
consumption
alternatives: shift from
unsustainable to sustain-
able consumption.
Sufciency: limit
the total level of
consumption.
Affordability
and fairness: reduce
inequality and ensure
that all are capable of
meeting their basic needs
and of participating
socially.
9
Executive SummaryBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Using this analysis and input from experts in poli-
cy, academia and business, we propose a package
of eight mutually supportive areas of reform in the
second part of the report. These policies would
help to signicantly accelerate the transition towards
a resilient economy for the UK and internationally:
1. A wellbeing budget for the UK that redenes
what we value in our economy and conse-
quently allocates a greater share of public and
private resources towards environmentally
sustainable and socially benecial outcomes.
2. A modernised set of government scal
rules in the UK that ensure the availability
of sufcient resources to complement the
wellbeing budget. This will enable the UK
government to borrow more at the current low
interest rates and invest in the low-carbon and
resource-efcient sectors that will sustain the
economic development of the country over the
coming decades.
3. Further backing for redirecting money to help
fund the green transition, via a new UK
national investment authority. This will play
an active role in the market by investing public
resources towards specic missions or
outcomes (such as meeting the UK’s net zero
target).
Table 1: Fields of action and intervention clusters of recommendations from the literature review
10
Executive SummaryBuilding a resilient economy
Content
4. On a nancial level, this shift in investments
is accelerated through mandatory nancial
risk assessments and their disclosure for
private banks that integrate non-traditional
environmental risks into their accounting and
risk assessment frameworks.
5. The disclosure of these risks is also a
precondition for green credit guidance. By
factoring climate and ecological risks into their
asset purchases and collateral frameworks,
central banks will help shift investments from
harmful activities to green sectors.
6. A land value tax to generate a new source
for nancing investments and generating
resources to support low-income households.
This policy will have negligible effects on eco-
nomic activity, but will help correct wealth and
power inequalities. Its taxes windfall increases
in land value while increasing the efciency
of land use in rural areas, and will reduce soil
sealing and the fragmentation of landscape.
7. Additional scal revenues from resource
caps. These ensure that increases in resource
efciency translate into an absolute rather
than a relative reduction in resource use. In
doing so they help control biodiversity loss
and ensure ecosystems can recover naturally
to a more sustainable state.
8. Environmental border taxes that put a
higher price on imports of environmentally
harmful goods. These will ensure that the
domestic economy is competitive, at the same
time they will reduce carbon emissions while
protecting biodiversity.
For each of these policies we identify several exist-
ing stakeholder coalitions and upcoming political
opportunities where they could be rened, promot-
ed and secured. Some require much greater inter-
national cooperation and are therefore more chal-
lenging, while others could be enacted immediately.
The policies presented here are mutually sup-
portive. Most address several of the intervention
areas listed in Table 1. A wellbeing budget for the
UK, the national investment authority, mandatory
nancial risk assessments and a green credit guid-
ance all aim to increase and strengthen investment
in the green economy. A modernised set of govern-
ment scal rules, a land value tax, and resource
caps create the necessary scal leeway. Resource
caps ensure that these policies are effective in
reducing resource use through absolute limits
and a dynamic steering effect via prices. Lastly, a
land value tax is one option among many to ensure
social acceptance, while environmental border
taxes aim to support domestic economic actors.
The recovery from COVID-19 presents a fork
in the road for governments. Bouncing back to
the pre-COVID days isn’t good enough. We can-
not afford to continue to tinker at the edges with
policies that achieve incremental change or are no
longer t for purpose. As the environmentalist Bill
McKibben solemnly noted, “winning slowly is the
same as losingin the context of climate change.
The research, analysis and synthesis presented
here offers a sample of the bold and transform-
ative policies we need to bounce forward and to
address the multiple crises we face collectively.
To do so, government, investors, businesses and
citizens need to make choices. Together, they need
to put in place regulation that breaks our depend-
ence on fossil fuels and extractive economic activi-
ties and propels the UK along a carbon-neutral, low
resource and high wellbeing pathway. This report
is an invitation. We are aware the proposals are
far-reaching. But we are convinced they are nec-
essary. To mitigate the costs of future crises, we
need the courage to do something new. With this
report, we invite you to dare, so that the prosperi-
ty of today will benet our children tomorrow and
we can give them a greater chance to thrive on a
bountiful planet.
11
IntroductionBuilding a resilient economy
Content
» COVID-19 has shown that avoid-
ing crises is not just a moral issue
– it is also an economic question. «
Crises tend to encourage short-term thinking.
1
When facing a crisis, people tend to react impul-
sively to end it be it in relationships, business,
nance or policy. This has been no different during
the COVID-19 crisis. Many governments respond-
ed quickly and with extensive effect. By April 2020,
leaders around the world had collectively mobi-
lised $ 9 trillion to buffer against the economic
impacts of lockdown measures.
2
In the UK alone,
176.7 billion were made available as an immedi-
ate scal response to the crisis.
3
The scale of these investments is impressive.
But at the same time, the COVID-19 crisis has
made clear how much crises can cost. Only through
such unprecedented public investment and by rad-
ically restricting public life closing kindergartens,
schools and businesses could the worst be pre-
vented. The countries that did not react swiftly and
underestimated the crisis, such as Sweden, have
paid for this with many lives.
4, 5
The actions focused on the short-term saved
lives. However, while politicians respond to the
immediate dangers, there is a direct lesson to be
learnt: Crises are expensive, and they can cause
economic disaster. Societies would, therefore, do
well to invest in preventative measures.
Some crises, like COVID-19, are difcult to
anticipate. Others, however, are foreseeable cli-
mate change and increasing biodiversity loss, for
example. In the interest of long-term economic
stability, policymakers must face this fact today
and work to limit climate change and the break-
down of ecosystems. Not only because doing so
can decrease the risk of future pandemics
6
: as
COVID-19 has demonstrated, avoiding crisis is not
just a moral issue, but also an economic question.
Many international scientic organisations, includ-
ing the IPCC
7
, the IBES
8
and the recent WEF report
on “The Future of Nature and Business”
9
, have high-
lighted that a fundamental transformation of todays
socio-economic systems is needed to mitigate cli
-
mate change and biodiversity loss. They provide a
broad consensus on the main areas needing reform
ranging from policy and nance to private sector
business and lifestyles. What has been missing is a
better understanding of how systemic change can
be operationalised and, given the urgency and inter
-
dependency of the issue, how the UK can effective-
ly support a fundamental transformation.
We have conducted a qualitative expert-led assess-
ment of 60 sources within the global literature on
systemic change. From this literature review, we
derived 270 policy proposals from across 12 topic
clusters, pertaining to four stakeholder groups:
policy, nance, private sector business and peo-
ple. Of these, we have selected eight key policies
for a more detailed elaboration, based on three
criteria: feasible and topical in the UK (relevance),
contribute to recovery from the COVID-19 crisis
(COVID-19 suitability) and have high transforma-
tive potential (transformativity).
Introduction
With this report, we seek to close this gap.
Our work aims to provide:
1. A denition of systemic change
2. An overview of the main policy areas
needing reform, of barriers to change
and transformative policy options
3. A set of eight policy priorities for
the UK that could also inspire
international action
Aim of the report
12
IntroductionBuilding a resilient economy
Content
This report contributes to multiple policy discus-
sions. The options outlined here add to the list of
options for change in the Dasgupta Review, com-
missioned by the UK Treasury, to address the bio-
diversity crisis. This analysis also provides guid-
ance for the effective implementation of the UK’s
net-zero legislation, circular economy strategies
and COVID-19 recovery programs.
We focus on policy actions aimed at adjusting
the structure of the economic system through legal
frameworks or legislation, to influence behaviour
i. e. actors’ collective decision making and in doing
so achieve far-reaching change. This recognises
that institutions are performative: the economic
and institutional framework is a key determinant
of how funds are invested, how and what business-
es produce and how people live and consume.
The report is structured as follows:
1. Chapter one presents our interpretation of the
main challenges that are rooted in the eco-
nomics of biodiversity, which we will present
here drawing on the insights of The Dasgupta
Review
10
. We then provide our denitions of a
resilient economy and systemic change.
2. Chapter two provides a short synopsis of the
methodology used in the literature review and
the stakeholder consultation.
These introductory chapters are followed by two
parts that summarise the results:
Part 1 provides an overview of the barriers
that hinder systemic change, categorised into
four areas of action: policy, nance, business,
and people. In this chapter, we also sum-
marise the boldest and most transformative
policy solutions to overcome these barriers,
that we found in literature.
Part 2 further elaborates on the eight key
policy proposals in detail and explains the
rationale behind their prioritisation. Every
policy proposal includes a section on
implementation and the associated barriers
and enablers, inspirational practices, windows
of opportunity and potential stakeholder
coalitions.
Chapter Five explores how systemic change
is as much about narratives of change and
collaboration, as it is about policymaking.
Many policymakers know that current
measures will not be enough to tackle
todays environmental crisis, but, in the
face of groupthink, only a few dare to
call for more ambition. With this report
we hope to encourage those involved in
public administration to speak up.
The report is an invitation to question and
consider new solutions. We do not claim
to have found all the solutions. Rather, we
aim to start a necessary discussion to think
outside the box. We are aware that some
of the solutions we present may seem
unusual or too ambitious. However, we
believe that the time has come to discuss
more transformative measures in the polit-
ical arena, and doubt that anything less
would sufce to address the magnitude of
todays challenges. The costs of inaction
are too high.
An invitation to think about
systemic change
13
Background Building a resilient economy
Content
» The extinction rate has
accelerated enormously, being
up to 100 times higher than in
the past. «
A recent study by the Potsdam Institute for Cli-
mate Change showed that limiting global warm-
ing to below two-degrees Celsius, as agreed in the
Paris Agreement, would be economically efcient
11
,
while an abundance of literature has conrmed
that costs of climate change will be astronomical.
12
While such studies are subject to uncertainty, mod-
elling, data and valuation choices, they point in the
same direction: the costs of climate change will
be high. Some of these costs are already evident
today. One consequence of climate change is the
devastating loss of natural habitats and the asso-
ciated ecosystem services. Together with resource
consumption, land-use change, pollution and inva-
sive species, these drivers have brought the global
ecosystem to the brink of collapse.
13
Ecosystems are responsible for purifying water
and air; providing food, wood, and biomass; regu-
lating climate and delicate water cycles; and pro-
viding natural amenities that humans use for recre-
ation and education. Take bees, for example: They
contribute between $ 233 billion to $ 577 billion
to global food production and support basic eco-
system functioning through their pollination activ-
ities
14
, this economic and ecological value goes
largely unnoticed and unprotected. All these valu-
able ecosystem services are at risk. While current
extinction rates for species are hard to assess, they
may lay somewhere between 1–2 every week
15
.
There is wide agreement that the extinction rate
has accelerated enormously, being up to 100 times
higher than in the past.
16
For example, in 2003, New York has
designated a huge nature reserve and
$ 150 million annually for its preservation
– but not for moral reasons. The nature
reserve puries water and the construction
of a comparable water purication plant
to replace this natural service would cost
$ 8 to 10 billion. Preserving biodiversity
is similarly economically efcient.
Addressing biodiversity loss
» Economic growth is not the goal
in and of itself, but a means of
reaching a number of other goals,
which collectively create economic
stability. «
To understand the economics of biodiversity and
the value of nature, HM Treasury (the UK Depart-
ment of Finance) recently commissioned a report
on the economics of biodiversity. Dasgupta dis-
cusses two scenarios for ending the degradation of
the biosphere by 2030, which depend on the “ef-
ciency with which we convert the biospheres goods
and services into GDP”.
17
In a “Green Growth” sce-
nario, this efciency would need to almost quad-
ruple, from 2.5 % to 9.1 % by 2030 an unprece-
dented and unlikely rate of innovation. He there-
fore outlines a second scenario, an economy with
constant economic output (GDP) from now until
2030, where efciency would onlyneed to dou-
Background
The economics of biodiversity and
the need for systemic change
14
Background Building a resilient economy
Content
ble a still unlikely, but more likely scenario. The
second scenario, essentially a “stagnating econo-
myby current standards, is a headache for econ-
omists, especially in a crisis period.
Pillars of economic and political stability, includ-
ing servicing debts, investment, providing jobs and
ghting inequality, all seem to demand economic
growth. Economic growth is not the goal in itself,
but a means of reaching a number of other goals,
which collectively create economic stability.
The social, economic, and political aspects of
the current economic system demand growth to
ensure stability in the short term. However, in pur-
suing short-term economic growth, policymakers
put long-term stability at risk by trading in envi-
ronmental health and function, transgressing plan-
etary boundaries and risking costs for public budg-
ets from the environmental crisis.
Economic Stability and Resilience
Stability is a rather static concept. First and fore-
most, it means that important system variables
such as unemployment, inequality or temperatures
have a predictable level of variation around a mean.
To talk about how policy can escape the dilemma of
choosing whether to preserve short-term or long-
term stability, we must introduce another concept:
“resilience. Resilience adds a dynamic component
to the concept of stability. While stability is about
the magnitude and strength of change, resilience
denes the ability to cope with change, especially
massive change such as shocks and crises. Stabili-
ty in the long-term can therefore be achieved both
by limiting the size of change or by developing an
ability to adapt to and recover from change.
Inspired by Andrew Mitchell
18
, we dene resil-
ience as “the ability to absorb and recover from
shocks”. Long-term stability requires a resilient
economy. An economy that is able to react to mas-
sive change and at the same time reduce the risk
of such change. For the post-COVID recovery to
create a resilient economy, it must transform both
structures and means of living to enable the sys-
tem to react to large shocks, while also reducing
the risk of such shocks.
In this sense, out of all the dimensions of resil-
ience
19
, two aspects of a resilient economy are cen-
tral to this report:
1. Safeguarding environmental resilience:
A resilient economy reduces the risk of future
environmental shocks and enhances
environmental resilience through a reduction
of drivers of biodiversity loss. Green inno -
vation and a structural transformation of the
economy towards sustainable business
models and lifestyles can reduce pressure
on the environment. Investment in ecological
function and recovery can boost both
ecological as well as economic resilience,
if employment and income are coupled with
a healthy environment.
2. Strengthening socio-economic resilience:
By safeguarding environmental resilience,
a resilient economy reduces the long-term
economic risks of environmental crisis. At the
same time, a resilient economy increases its
capacity to recover from shocks by liberating
its stability from the need to grow. A resilient
economy can ensure employment generation,
equality and debt reduction even in a stagnat-
ing economic environment. Such resilience
would require rethinking how we generate
wellbeing and rearranging how we pursue it,
as well as how debt is managed, how jobs are
created, and how inequality is reduced.
15
Background Building a resilient economy
Content
Strategies for addressing
the biodiversity loss
To pave the way for a resilient economy, two
central strategies are required:
1. Green innovation: We need huge leaps
in green innovation to increase material
productivity and efciency, as specied
by Dasgupta, to allow businesses to
produce and society in general to
enjoy as much material prosperity as
is available for distribution. Within the
ecological limits of the planet, policies
that encourage green innovation can
reduce the negative ecological effects
of economic activity and could enable
a transition to a less resource-intense
and climate-friendly economy, as
sought by the UKs Net-Zero Regulation
and the Circular Economy Package.
2. Growth independence: However, while
green innovation has to increase,
policymakers today must prepare for
the fact that these innovations are likely
to still not be sufcient, as recognised
by Dasgupta. It is possible that
ecological collapse can only be avoided
by a courageous restructuring of
todays economic systems: decoupling
economic and political stability from
economic growth.
The matter of which of these strategies is
the right one is highly disputed.
20, 21, 22, 23, 24, 25,
26, 27
Given the uncertainty of the future, we
must apply both rather than debate which
one is right.
Understanding and dening
systemic change
Many researchers, including the IPCC
28
, the IPBES
29
and the WEF
30
have highlighted that transformative
change is necessary to mitigate the acceleration of
the climate crisis and biodiversity loss. They agree
on the main areas of reform, ranging from policy
and nance to business and lifestyles. However,
what is missing thus far, is a better understanding
of how to operationalise systemic change.
We dene systemic change as institutional change
31
that drastically decelerate or mitigate the break-
down of ecosystems, either directly through pol-
icies that protect and restore natural habitats or
indirectly, e. g. through policies that address the
drivers of biodiversity loss like climate change.
Douglass North denes institutions as con-
straints that structure political, economic and
social interaction. They are made up of formal con-
straints (constitutions, laws, property rights), infor-
mal constraints (sanctions, taboos, customs, tra-
ditions, codes of conduct), and their enforcement
characteristics.
32
In this report, we go beyond the cultural and
informal dimensions of institutional change. Often,
responsibility is redirected to the peoples cul-
ture. In those cases, the assumption is that people
have to change their values rst, which would then
translate into different policies afterwards.
33
In our
assessment, we recognise the reciprocal nature of
the interaction between formal and explicit institu-
tions like policy, regulations, laws, agreements and
informal value systems and culture.
34
We assume
that policy can drive cultural change, rather than
only being an outcome of it. This, however, does
not take anything away from the necessity of infor-
mal cultural change independent of policy.
16
Background Building a resilient economy
Content
Criteria for systemic change
Systemic change can be understood as changing the formal and explicit
(policies, practices, resource flows) as well as informal and semi-implicit
(power dynamics, relationships and connections) and implicit (mental
models) institutions of today’s economies.
35
In order to be considered systemic
changes, proposed institutional changes must full the following criteria:
1. Structural: Increase the relevance of sustainability and wellbeing aspects in
formal institutions like governance processes, legislation and international
agreements (explicit level).
2. Root-cause related: Address the root causes of today’s environmental and
social challenges (semi-implicit and implicit level): power imbalances, lack
of valuation of nature, growth dependence, narrow value systems in society,
business, nance and policy, and mindset.
3.
Cross-cutting: Influence the behaviour of the majority of actors within
different economic areas (policy, business, nance, citizens) across different
economic sectors (manufacturing, agriculture, energy …) on a long-term
basis, rather than changing the behaviour of only one single actor.
4. Transformative: Can be incremental in the short-run (e. g. biodiversity
labels for nancial products), if they contribute to systemic change in
the long-run (e. g. directing investments across sectors into nature conser-
vation) and help overcome path dependencies that create lock-ins
in existing structures.
17
MethodologyBuilding a resilient economy
Content
To identify a set of key policies for systemic change
toward a resilient economy, we conducted a qual-
itative expert-led assessment of literature on sys-
temic change, building on our experience in the
eld of transformation sciences and new econom-
ics. In doing so, we conducted the following steps:
1. Identication of sources
Firstly, we identied 60 sources on systemic
change from the global literature based on expert
input. Criteria for the selection of sources can be
found in the appendix.
2. Identication of barriers
and transformative policy
proposals / options
Secondly, we identied 270 policy proposals from
these sources. Our literature review concentrated
on proposals for systemic changes, as dened in
the previous chapter.
From this set of proposals, we identied 12 topic
clusters on systemic change along the four clusters
of actors. These are:
Policy: multidimensional indicators,
monitoring capacity, and legal frameworks;
scal policy and growth independence;
limiting power and empowerment for change.
Finance: metrics for the long-term; mandates
and legal interpretations.
Business: protability, investment and
innovation; disclosure, reporting and
assessment; business models.
Citizens: sustainable consumption
alternatives; sufciency; affordability and
fairness.
Part One of the report will describe the clusters
and associated policies in more detail.
36
In terms of
content, we have enriched the chapters with addi-
tional sources, when an important aspect was still
missing.
3. Denition of eight key
policies for the UK
Out of these 12 clusters and associated proposals,
this report elaborates on eight key policies that:
are feasible & topical in the UK (relevance),
contribute to recovery from the COVID-19
crisis (COVID-19 suitability),
have a high-transformative impact
37
(transformative potential).
At the same time, additional conditions apply to the
whole set of policies, rather than single policies:
Balance: To nd the balance between feasi-
bility and transformative impact the overall
set of policies includes at least one less
feasible, but highly transformative proposal.
International dimension: To account for the
UK’s international role, at least one proposal
should have an international dimension
attached.
Side effects: The set of policy should be com-
plemented with proposals to reduce negative
side effects of other proposals, to ensure
consistency (e. g. environmental border taxes,
land taxation)
Methodology
18
Building a resilient economy
Content
4. Expert consultation
In order to “sense-checkthe policy proposals that
emerged from the literature review and from expert
input, we conducted a stakeholder poll amongst
leading policy experts, academics and commenta-
tors who work on relevant questions in the UK and
beyond. We invited almost 100 participants and
received a response rate of approximately 30 %.
Participants in the survey were asked to:
Reflect on whether the shortlist of proposed
policy changes met our criteria for being
both transformative, and possible, in the UK
context.
Nominate the three policy changes they would
be most likely to advocate for and why, and
to point to any policies we should consider
adding to our list.
Advice as to what strategy and approach
would help to secure adoption of the
respective policies in the UK.
While not a large-scale representative poll, this
deliberate, strategic sampling of professionals
with relevant expertise has provided condence
in the suite of policies we set out below. To aug-
ment the poll input, we also posed similar ques-
tions to a different set of policy experts, including
UK government ofcials, at a webinar hosted by the
WWF in June 2020.
Part 1
Overview of barriers
and policy proposals for
changing the economic
and nancial system
This part provides an overview of the main areas of reform, as well
as barriers and transformative policy options, categorised into four
areas of action: policy, nance, business and citizens.
22
IntroductionBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Drawing on our assessment of the global liter-
ature on systemic change, this part provides an
overview of the main areas of reform, as well as
barriers and transformative policy options.
To this end, we consider four elds of action in the
following four sub-chapters: Policy, Finance, Busi-
ness and citizens. The literature offers a wide range
of insight on what prevents these actors from
changing their behaviour and what policy can do
about it.
We faced two challenges when synthesising
the literature. The rst challenge were the highly
differing levels of abstraction of proposals found
in the literature, ranging from abstract propos-
als such as “internalise environmental costs” to
very concrete proposals such as “increase equity
requirements for unsustainable credits”. The chal-
lenge was therefore to align proposals to a similar
level of abstraction. The second challenge was to
identify the target group for policy proposals. For
example, in the case of the proposal to “ban adver-
tising of environmentally harmful products”, the
question of whether the proposal is attributed to
the target group that implements the policy (busi-
ness) or target group that should change its behav-
iour (citizens).
To align levels of abstraction and consistently
assign target groups, we identied 12 interven-
tion clusters for policy makers (see Table 1). The
clusters are to be understood as objectives, the
achievement of which influences the behaviour of
each actor. Some proposals in the literature are
directly reflected in the objective, others in the
associated policy proposals.
A detailed summary of all literature sources can
be found in the Appendix.
It is important to stress that these clusters are all
interwoven. There are many synergies but also
many conflicts between them. Many of the goals
can only be achieved in tandem with others. For
example, consumption change is only possible
through the availability of product alternatives, as
well as the purchasing power required to access
them. Power cannot only be directly restricted
through prohibition, but it can be influenced indi-
rectly through tax structures and new corporate
models. By cross-referencing, we point out possi-
ble links between the objectives in the chapter.
Introduction
Policy Finance Business Citizens
Multidimensional
indicators, moni-
toring capacity, and legal
frameworks: ensure
political decision making
addresses the environ-
ment and wellbeing with
equal weight on the
economic aspects.
Fiscal policy and
growth independ-
ence: increase the space
for scal interventions to
support a green and just
transition and decouple
economic stability from
economic growth.
Limiting power
and empowerment
for change: reduce
economic and democratic
power imbalances.
Mandates and legal
interpretations:
include environmental
and social objectives in
the targets of public insti-
tutions such as central
banks and development
banks.
Metrics for the
long-term: integrate
environmental categories
and extend the time hori-
zon in risk assessments.
Shifting
Protability:
internalise the costs of
environmental damage.
Sustainable invest-
ment and innova-
tion: shift investment and
techno logy from resource-
intensive activities to
those that are less resource-
intensive but more
labour-intensive.
Non-nancial
disclosure, report-
ing and accountability:
include environmental
objectives in business
reporting standards.
Sustainable busi-
ness models:
Support business models
that focus on sustainabil-
ity and well being and
create a level playing
eld.
Sustainable
consumption
alternatives: shift from
unsustainable to sustain-
able consumption.
Sufciency: limit
the total level of
consumption.
Affordability
and fairness: reduce
inequality and ensure
that all are capable of
meeting their basic needs
and of participating
socially.
23
IntroductionBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Table 1: Fields of action and intervention clusters of recommendations from the literature review
24
Policy and governanceBuilding a resilient economy
Content
» Governments have often
fallen short of implementing
policies that translate agreed
environmental and social
objectives into action. «
Policy and governance are one central lever in
bringing about a resilient economy. By setting
legal and institutional frameworks, governance
shapes people’s attitudes and behaviour, and the
interactions between actors (including govern-
ments, nancial institutions, business and civil
society).
38
Policy could either reproduce existing
inequalities or support low-income groups in the
transition to a more sustainable society. Policy can
also incentivise or disincentivise certain invest-
ment, innovation, production, and consumption;
making it a key measure in the effort to overcome
path-dependencies that lock in current modes of
unsustainable production, consumption, and gen-
eration of wellbeing.
39
Governments have often fallen short of imple-
menting policies that translate agreed environ-
mental and social objectives into action. While
objectives such as the Sustainable Development
Goals (SDGs) and the Paris Agreement are impor-
tant steps towards a resilient economy, , the world
is not well placed to achieve most of the SDGs.
40
Similarly, global policy commitments to reduce
greenhouse gas emissions are insufcient to halve
GHG-emissions by 2030, which is required to limit
global warming to 1.5 °C.
41
Even the existing weak
climate pledges are unlikely to be achieved. The
policy efforts of the UK, the second largest con-
tributor to CO
2
emissions in the European Union
(10.7 %), have fallen short. The Paris Agreement
binds the UK to reducing emissions by at least
40 % of 1990 levels by 2030, and in June 2019
the UK adopted a net zero emissions reduction
target for 2050. Achieving any of these targets
remains unlikely, especially given that the UK’s
expenditures into climate mitigation ($ 100 billion)
decreased by 35 % between 2014 and 2017.
42, 43
Challenges
Barriers to policy change
It remains difcult for most governments to pro-
mote policymaking that is suitable for tackling
the complex challenges of the 21
st
century, for a
myriad of reasons. An assessment of the literature
can be summarised in two clusters: Governance &
political value systems, and power imbalances.
Compartmentalised governance
and short-term focused political
value systems
Firstly, managing the global commons in the face
of international economic competition requires
collective action and enforcement. The non-bind-
ing nature of international climate agreements,
with unclear or inadequate compliance rules, has
not succeeded in raising political ambition at a
national level to take meaningful climate action.
44
Secondly, one of the reasons for this lack of
interest in stronger international agreements are
political value systems and the associated gov-
ernance processes that prioritise short-term eco-
nomic impacts of policies, rather than long-term
environmental and other social impacts. Many
policies lack an evaluation of long-term environ-
mental and social impacts and are shaped accord-
ing to a short-term agenda of economic growth
even though long-term ecological and social harm
also translates into immense scal expenses down
the line. Economic growth is associated with high
levels of wellbeing, debt reduction, lower inequal-
Policy and governance
25
Policy and governanceBuilding a resilient economy
Content
ity and employment generation. Therefore, it is
seen as the preeminent means to achieve the most
fundamental socio-economic policy objectives.
This and a range of further lock-ins, such as media
attention, geopolitical power competition, pri-
vate interests and lobbying, make it very difcult
for policymakers to break away from economic
growth as a policy objective and argue in favour of
a wider set of indicators and policy measures.
45, 46
Thirdly, political value systems that prioritise
short-term economic policy impacts are tied to
economic attitudes and theories in public institu-
tions, which stem from a narrow reading of eco-
nomics. Economists shape how policymakers per-
ceive and measure the world, affecting the deci-
sions they make.
47, 48, 49, 50
The uncompromising
focus on economic growth is one example.
51
Anoth-
er is the focus of public policy on market-based,
supply-side solutions to economic problems For
example, prior to the COVID-19 crisis, policymak-
ers – both globally and in the UK – were convinced
that solutions would surface through the free mar-
ket, which policy should not excessively regulate.
52,
53
This reading made it difcult to implement regu-
latory measures such as bans or obligations. These
may be economically less cost-effective, but they
are effective in terms of their impact.
Fourthly, certain features of existing demo-
cratic systems pose additional barriers to long-
term oriented policymaking. To ensure re-elec-
tion, political agendas tend to focus on actions with
measurable impacts during their term.
54
Power imbalances
These structural lock-ins of policy and governance
systems are reinforced by actors pursuing short-
term prots and translate into power imbalanc-
es. In the UK, 0.1 % of business receives 47.8 %
of total revenues and provides 39.5 % of the coun-
trys jobs.
55
In the US, the “Big Three” index funds,
Vanguards, BlackRock and State Street make up
96 % of the shareholdings of Fortune 250 compa-
nies and exercise signicant influence over share-
holder proposals, especially on proposals relat-
ed to the environment, social matters and govern-
ance.
56
This concentration of power, reinforced by
their capacity to organise lobbying and their strong
political networks, gives them tremendous lever-
age when it comes to public decision making.
57
The
resulting power imbalance between policymakers,
business and civil society hampers any progress
towards sustainable solutions.
58
Solutions
Options for systemic change
Drawing on the reviewed literature, we propose
several actions to overcome these barriers. Policy
actions can be grouped into three clusters: govern-
ance related issues, scal policy and growth inde-
pendence and power. We summarise key argu-
ments and invite readers to consult the sources
provided in the footnotes.
Multidimensional Indicators,
monitoring capacity, and legal
frameworks
Political decision-making should give equal
weight to the environment, wellbeing and eco-
nomic aspects in order to build ecological resil-
ience and social wellbeing. This requires develop-
ing and implementing policies that consider short-
as well as long-term environmental and social
impacts. To achieve this, governments should
replace purely economic measures as indicators
of progress that guide political decision-making,
such as Gross Domestic Product
59
which does not
account for the negative environmental impacts
of economic growth, or the negative impacts on
26
Policy and governanceBuilding a resilient economy
Content
human health and social relationships. A group
of countries, including New Zealand and Scotland,
are exploring alternatives using Wellbeing Budg-
ets which rely on a multidimensional set of indi-
cators.
60, 61
The alternatives are there.
62
What is
missing is their implementation and their actual
use in political decision-making processes.
Indicators are not only measurements but
can also determine accountability and effective-
ly change policy decisions, if they are incorporat-
ed into policy design and decision-making pro-
cesses. This would require methods, models and a
community of users able to understand and evalu-
ate the quantitative as well as qualitative impacts
of policies on wellbeing and the environment, as
exists for economic indicators.
63
Some argue that
such skills should be accompanied by training in
systems thinking, to build capacity in public insti-
tutions in understanding feedback mechanisms
between the economy, society, environment and
associated tipping points.
64, 65
Such indicators for
policies should also be used to assess existing sub-
sidies and tax systems, subjecting them to a critical
analysis of their domestic and international envi-
ronmental and social impacts.
66, 67, 68
Governance systems would need to be legal-
ly obligated to adopt long-term criteria to ensure
that an enhanced understanding of environmen-
tal, social and economic impacts and interlinkag-
es inform policies. The upcoming Environment Act
in the UK or the Climate Law in the EU are impor-
tant steps in securing obligations among poli-
cymakers to incorporate future factors and the
needs of nature into decision-making. Proposals
in the literature include the legal recognition of
the rights of nature, as in New Zealand, Bolivia or
Ecuador.
69
A new democratically elected chamber
with the responsibility of representing the inter-
ests of future generations could have veto power
on decisions with long-term impacts.
70
This would
increase pressure to nd solutions that mediate
conflicts between the present and future inter-
est groups. One important initiative in this vein is
the Wellbeing of Future Generations Act in Wales,
which requires public bodies to think about the
long-term impact of their decisions, in terms of
their effects on persistent problems such as pov-
erty, health inequalities and climate change, offer-
ing opportunities to bring about long-lasting, posi-
tive change for current and future generations.
Fiscal policy and growth
independence
However, for long-termism to be embedded in pol-
icy, another structural barrier must be overcome.
The puzzle of economic growth dependency needs
to be solved.
71, 72
The COVID-19 crisis has demon-
strated how steadfast public perception is that sta-
bility depends on economic growth. Placing social,
environmental and economic stability at the cen-
tre of concern is not merely a matter of political will.
Economies today seem to be structurally depend-
ent on the continuous expansion of the economy.
Becoming growth independent means nd-
ing other ways of generating employment, pro-
moting equality and reducing debt. It is not about
de-growing the economy. It is about recognising
the fundamental uncertainty regarding the future.
Due to the complexity and amount of assump-
tions involved, neither science nor policy can fore-
see how stronger environmental commitments and
regulation will affect aggregate economic growth
in the long-term. It would be great, if green growth
and technology solved the problem and ensured
that today's economies stayed within planetary
boundaries while growing. However, as outlined
recently in the Dasgupta Interim Report
73
, innova-
tion is likely to be too slow for addressing urgent
environmental challenges. Becoming growth inde-
pendent is about preparing for the possibility
that ecological resilience can only be maintained
through a steady-state economy or a decrease in
consumption and production. In addition, policy-
27
Policy and governanceBuilding a resilient economy
Content
makers must rethink scal policy. A green trans-
formation requires substantial public invest-
ment. At the same time, it will be crucial to invest
where the economy creates real public use-val-
ue: health care, education, nursing care, public
parks and clean energy, transport and infrastruc-
ture.
74, 75
To do so, sufcient amounts of resources
must be available. Thereby, regulations such as the
Stability and Growth Pact in the EU, or the Char-
ter for Budget Responsibility in the UK dene how
much money can be spent and what it is spent for.
Changing the legislations that assess scal space
can create space for new investments.
These new investments can, for instance, be
directed by a Green Investment Bank
76
to where
they minimise ecological risks and maximise social
value. However, such investments often face high-
er debts. Charles Goodhart and Michael Hudson
therefore propose a modern form of debt jubi-
lees to deal with this challenge, where those forms
of debt most largely contributing to income and
wealth inequalities could be cancelled by funding
from a land or property tax.
77, 78
Additional resources can come from taxa-
tion on activities that produce damage instead
of value, and by ghting tax evasion and offshor-
ing. Legislation denes how much money is taxed
and who pays that money, thus guiding economic
development in a certain direction. More taxes can
be collected by reducing tax advantages for fossil
fuel industries
79, 80
or implementing taxes on activ-
ities that are harmful to the environment and the
public good (e. g. carbon taxes
81, 82
). Policy would
thereby internalise external effects from econom-
ic activities and incentivise the right kind of behav-
iour. Taxes can also come from skimming off eco-
nomic rents: increases in value that occur not by
the personal investment of people, but through the
investment of the State
83, 84
or are not associated
with real economic activities (e. g. a nancial trans-
action tax
85
).
Limiting power and
empowerment for change
Policymakers will face considerable resistance to
change, if policies are accompanied by concen-
trated impacts that run counter to the interests
of powerful actors. To prevent this, policies that
combat power inequalities are important. Often,
money results in political power (in the sense of an
individual’s or group’s ability to influence political
decision making), over the use of public resourc-
es and the implementation of policies
86
. Propos-
als to break these power imbalances by distribut-
ing money more equally range from redistributing
economic rents through land tax reforms
87
, pro-
gressive wealth and inheritance taxes
88
to struc-
tural approaches like business unbundling, strong-
er regulation for mergers to a change in owner-
ship structures as a whole
89, 90
, to maximum sizes
of companies
91
, income limits
92, 93
or basic income
schemes
94
.
Tackling power imbalances is not only about
limiting the power of influential actors, but also
about increasing power of less powerful groups.
One way to achieve this is to extend policy coher-
ence boundaries to non-state actors that operate
outside or across the borders of national legal regu-
lation.
95
This includes corporate norms and compli-
ance systems, new business models, new ways of
forming civil society groups, the use of social media,
etc. Policy coherence needs new means of govern-
ance. New forms of collaboration between poli-
cy and the private as well as the civil society sec-
tor can promote policies that cut across functional
boundaries to create solutions that anticipate soci-
etal and global dependencies. Citizen assemblies
can become a new form of policy design and inno-
vation.
96
28
FinanceBuilding a resilient economy
Content
The vast majority of nancial institutions fail to
integrate environmental and long-term factors
into their decision making. This leads to a large
misallocation of funds. On the one hand, funding the
transition to a sustainable economy is estimated to
cost between US $ 5–7 trillion per year until 2030.
However, public and private nance only mobilis-
es US $ 2.5 trillion, leaving a signicant shortfall of
funds
97, 98
. On the other hand, nancial institutions
continue to fund unsustainable economic activities.
Bond and equity markets are, for instance, overex-
posed to fossil fuel intensive and polluting sectors.
This means that a large amount of capital is being
invested in environmentally harmful business, rath-
er than sustainable alternatives. Notably, this also
applies to the seemingly “market neutral” asset
purchasing programs of central banks
99
. A similar
dynamic exists in bank-based nance. It has been
estimated that banks across the world have invest-
ed a total of US $ 2.7 trillion in fossil fuel projects
and companies between 2016 and 2019; after the
signing of the Paris Agreement
100
. Of this amount,
UK banks alone accounted for US $ 100 billion
between 2016 and 2018
101
. In addition, the high
exposure of the UK’s nancial sector to mortgages
on real estate with low energy efciency illustrates
how urgently the nancial system needs reform, if
it is to become an enabler rather than a barrier to
environmental sustainability
102
.
This collective misallocation of funding has
enormous implications in the way of destabilis-
ing the planet’s environmental systems. Since
economic and nancial systems are embedded
in earth systems, nancial stability itself is at risk.
Now realising the systemic risks for nancial sta-
bility that arise from climate change, which are
estimated at US $ 43 trillion in nancial losses by
2100
103
, regulators and central banks have start-
ed to explore and integrate climate-related risks
into their work.
Climate-related risks are, however, not the only
concern for nance. A WWF sponsored study has
recently estimated potential losses from ongoing
biodiversity-related loss at a minimum of US $ 10
trillion by 2050
104
. Another study sponsored by
UNEP suggests these risks are heavily concentrat-
ed in a few sectors, including agriculture, apparel
and resource extraction and use
105
.
Notably, such high-level scenarios are likely to
underestimate the real risks that materialise. They
are based on assumptions about highly interde-
pendent and uncertain environmental, technolog-
ical and political trajectories. In light of this, recent
working papers from the Bank for International Set-
tlements
106
and the UCLs Institute for Innovation
and Public Purpose
107
have pointed out the limita-
tions of relying on modelling. Citing the precaution-
ary principle and the fundamental uncertainty that
comes with changes to the planets natural sys-
tems, the authors advocate rapid and transform-
ative action to avoid potentially catastrophic out-
comes for nature, the economy and nance.
Financial institutions and their supervisors
need to better incorporate environmental criteria
into their allocative decision making and their risk
assessments. Ethical investors, ESG rating agen-
cies and NGOs have pioneered the work on dis-
closing and understanding the data on how nance
contributes to and is exposed to environmental
risks. Most recently, initiatives like the FSB TCFD
have added much-needed rigorousness and scope
to these assessments. Nonetheless, disclosure
alone remains insufcient if nancial institutions
are unable or unwilling to process it.
108
This needs
to go further by making sure that this data is used
Finance
» The collective misallocation
of private funding has enormous
implications in the way of
destabilising the planets
environmental systems.«
29
FinanceBuilding a resilient economy
Content
effectively. The priorities and mandates of regu-
lators need to change. Additionally, actors across
the nancial system including nancial institutions,
regulators and service providers (e. g. rating agen-
cies, index providers) need to develop common
metrics and methodologies that make the relevant
environmental issues clear. Together, these shifts
could give rise to policies and investment practic-
es that better allocate funding.
Challenges
Barriers to a sustainable trans-
formation of the nancial system
There are, however, institutional and legal reasons
for the misallocation of funds and the failure to
take environmental issues into account.
Short-termism
The rst issue is that nancial institutions and their
regulators often only operate using a time horizon
of one business cycle, and thus, only look at what
happens in the next one to ve years
109, 110
. In addi-
tion, the practice of quarterly reporting has been
linked to short-termism by some observers
111
. The
associated longer-term environmental impacts and
risks of nancial transactions are often not consid-
ered and therefore not appropriately priced.
A second issue is that large nancial institu-
tions and investors are generally risk averse when
it comes to economic risks. This is because regu-
lation and mandates require that they do not gam-
ble with the contributions of pension savers or
insurance holders. While this is a sensible policy,
it also means that such nancial institutions dis-
play a status quo bias, which means that they are
greatly exposed to the current unsustainable econ-
omy, whereas alternative (possibly more sustain-
able, but less protable) businesses face a short-
age or increased cost of funding. This status quo
bias is further exacerbated by the use of indices
like the S & P 500 or the MSCI World as proxies for
“the market” against which risks and returns are
benchmarked. Such indices have been found to be
biased in favour of the fossil fuel industry and to
grant undue infrastructural power to index provid-
ers like MSCI, which make far-reaching decisions
about capital allocations.
112, 113
The inability of institutional investors to fund
sustainable projects is further exacerbated by
narrow legal interpretations of their responsibil-
ities (i. e. duciary duties). These postulate that
they need only take short-term prot maximisa-
tion into account
114
. A nal institutional issue is
the mismatch of scale across capital markets in
particular. Impactful environmental preservation
projects often have a volume of less than one mil-
lion euro or dollars, while the average green bond
requires a volume of 100 million EUR.
115
Lack of metrics
A second cluster of barriers concerns the lack of
common metrics for environmental and broader
sustainability indicators. While data and ratings
on Environmental, Social and Governance (ESG)
criteria abound, different methodologies make
standardisation and comparison difcult. The lack
of correlation between different providers has led
critics to adopt the term “alphabet soup” when
referring to ESG
116, 117, 118
. Some of the confusion of
ESG methodologies comes from the fact that data
providers often assess companies’ targets and pol-
icies instead of the actual environmental and social
outcomes. Initiatives like the EU’s upcoming green
taxonomy and the Task Force on Climate-relat-
ed Financial Disclosures (TCFD), as well as more
established frameworks such as the Global Report-
ing Initiative or the CDP (formerly Carbon Disclo-
sure Project), aim to enhance the clarity of envi-
30
FinanceBuilding a resilient economy
Content
ronment-related information. Most recently, sev-
eral organisations including the WWF and UNEP
launched the Taskforce for Nature-related Finan-
cial Disclosures
119
. Given increased deteriora-
tion of ecosystems and increased awareness of
nance and the economys dependence on natu-
ral systems
120
, this task force aims to improve the
reporting, metrics and data that nancial institu-
tions need in order to better understand their risks,
dependencies and impacts on nature by 2022.
These developments notwithstanding, the lack
of agreed upon and widely used metrics allows
nancial institutions to engage in “greenwashing”,
i. e. selecting the ESG measures that make their
portfolio look sustainable. This kind of ESG data
shopping, however, defeats the purpose of sustain-
able investment, since instead of reallocating cap-
ital towards sustainable businesses and projects,
existing assets are merely relabelled. In addition,
the “noise” that such competing methods gener-
ates, makes it harder to clearly identify the long-
term risks.
Culture and Policy Frameworks
Thirdly, there are barriers to sustainability in
nance that are related to but not completely cov-
ered in the institutional and legal barriers, which
we term culture and policy frameworks.
Financial practitioners tend to reflect little on
long-term and environmental impacts in nance
education and in the work environment. Instead,
short-termism and a narrow conception of mone-
tary prot are prioritised. This is reinforced by the
dominant metrics and tools that nancial prac-
titioners use. The ubiquity of narrow Cost Bene-
t Analysis and short-term nancial pricing mod-
els like the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) as
well as Modern Portfolio Theory more generally, are
prime examples of this dynamic.
A second broader issue is the overall policy
framework beyond the regulation of the nancial
sector (see Chapter 1). The materialisation of the
risks for unsustainable investments depends ulti-
mately on real economy policies. If, for instance, a
high carbon tax is implemented or internal com-
bustion engines are prohibited, this represents
a risk for those who currently invest in nancial
assets linked to these economic activities in the
literature, this issue is denoted by the concepts
of stranded assets and transition risks. If, howev-
er, nancial institutions do not believe that gov-
ernments will act forcefully, they have little incen-
tive to already factor in such transition risks today.
121
For this reason, focusing on risk disclosures in
nance only is unlikely to shift allocation patterns.
On the other hand, the point about the signi-
cance of real economy policies should not be over-
stated. Finance is not merely a reflection of the real
economy and reforms to the nancial system are
not only second-best strategies. Instead, there is
a two-way dynamic between nance and the real
economy. The nancial system processes informa-
tion from the real economy according to its own
institutional dynamics. Allocation decisions that
are made in this process not only reflect the cur-
rent real economy, but also contribute to the con-
struction of the future real economy.
122, 123
As such,
reforms of both the real economy and the nan-
cial system are needed to transition to a sustain-
able economy.
Solutions
The role of policy in setting
nance on course for tackling
today’s challenges
Institutional legacies, mandates and legal inter-
pretations are the outcomes of past political
choices and policies. Likewise, what is considered
today as standardised and “hard” nancial data is,
31
FinanceBuilding a resilient economy
Content
in fact, the outcome of legal and political process-
es
124
. The barriers to nance adopting and playing
its part in funding a sustainable transition is there-
fore not set in stone, and policymakers can rewrite
the rules of the game according to the altered pri-
orities that planetary emergencies demand. We
have identied two main clusters where policy can
intervene.
Mandates and legal
interpretations
In its simplest form, a mandate describes the
objectives of a public institution. Accordingly, a
body with political legitimacy like the UK Parliament
delegates the task of achieving certain goals to an
independent public body like the Bank of England
(BoE). In the context of nance, central banks and
regulators are the public institutions whose man-
dates are especially relevant. Mandates serve on the
one hand to ensure the consistency of policies pre-
scribed by regulators and central banks, since they
prevent politicians from creating confusion by con-
stantly adjusting policies. On the other hand, man-
dates prevent “mission creepon the part of these
institutions by clearly circumscribing their tasks.
Nonetheless, it is important to remember that
mandates remain based on political decisions and
that they reflect the context of those decisions. A
recent review of 135 central banks nds that only
13 % out of the reviewed institutions have a sus-
tainability-related mandate
125
. Some, like the BoE,
have a broader mandate that tasks them with con-
tributing to the government’s priorities. However,
due to different political priorities in the past, many
central banks, including the BoE, are still primari-
ly tasked with ensuring price stability (and more
recently nancial stability). This could make them
a target for criticisms of mission creep, should they
try to address environmental issues like climate
change
126
.
Legal interpretations, on the other hand, deter-
mine the meaning and implications of a concept in
regulation or any other piece of legislation. Such
clarication determines, for example, whether and
to what degree the task of maintaining nancial
stability forces central banks to address climate
change. Yet legal interpretations also impact private
nancial actors. For instance, the question of which
risks can be considered “nancially material” influ-
ences the reporting and risk assessments of nan-
cial institutions. Another example is the above-men-
tioned concept of duciary duty, which has implica-
tions for the allocation strategies of institutions like
pension funds. The list below outlines certain poli-
cies that could modify the cluster of mandates and
legal interpretations towards sustainability:
Democratic consultation on the purpose of the
nancial sector led by the Parliament, whose
outputs would be used to update the mandates
of the Bank of England and the Financial
Conduct Authority.
127
Clarify the meaning of materiality, so that it
accounts both for risks of dependencies of
nancial institutions on nature and for impacts
of nancing operations on nature (double
materiality)
128
.
Clarication of the non-nancial dimension of
duciary duties.
129
» Only 13 % of central banks
have a sustainability-related
mandate
32
FinanceBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Metrics for the long-term
Illumination of the links between the environment
and nance requires standardised measuring
techniques. While popularisation and increasing
sophistication of environmental metrics helped the
nancial sector to learn about environmental issues
in the past, these efforts have been insufcient in
anchoring sustainability concerns to nance. To
assess the risks to and impacts on nature, nan-
cial institutions and regulators need consistent, sci-
ence-based data that can be integrated into nan-
cial decision making and supervisory practices
respectively. There is a need for common standards,
mandatory disclosure and publicly backed method-
ologies. Some of the proposals that are related to
the question of metrics are listed below:
Support the development of a taxonomy of
economic activities.
130
Develop public labels that certify the
compatibility of nancial products with
biodiversity goals and ensure that biodiversity
is integrated into ESG [Environmental, social
and Governance] ratings. In the longer-term,
methodologies should be harmonised.
131
Make long-term and environmental risk
assessments obligatory for all nancial
institutions through prudential regulation
tools such as climate stress tests.
132, 133
Develop transition scenarios and stress tests
to assess how well nancial institutions are
aligned with the pathways towards a 1.5 °C
transition and a halt of biodiversity loss.
134, 135
Make environmental, long-term risk assess-
ments obligatory for all nancial institutions.
Make disclosure and reporting of “non-nan-
cial” information to regulators and the general
public obligatory for listed companies.
136, 137, 138
Make nancial institutions’ disclosure to
supervisors of climate-related risks and their
management obligatory.
139
Make reporting on climate change risk
mandatory.
140
Success story
The Task Force on Climate-Related Finan-
cial Disclosures (TCFD), hosted by the
Financial Stability Board (FSB), was put in
place to develop consistent, climate-relat-
ed nancial risk disclosures to help compa-
nies, banks and investors provide informa-
tion to stakeholders. Increasing the amount
of reliable information on nancial institu-
tions’ exposure to climate-related risks and
opportunities will strengthen the stability
of the nancial system, contribute to great-
er understanding of climate risks, and facil-
itate nancing the transition to a more sta-
ble and sustainable economy. This frame-
work requires businesses to report the cli-
mate-related impacts of their operations,
thus providing an accounting mechanism
that claries progress toward wellbeing
goals. To date, the TCFD has gathered over
1020 supporters representing a market cap-
italisation of over US $ 12 trillion
141
. In addi-
tion, regulators like the UK’s Department for
Work and Pensions have started to explore
the option of making the TCFD framework
mandatory
142
.
33
BusinessBuilding a resilient economy
Content
» Efciency gains might be 
realised in one sector, but they
are often offset by an increase
in production in another. «
Business
143
has a major influence on the prospects
for a sustainable economy and socially just socie-
ty. The private sector is a key economic actor via
its immediate role as employer, purchaser, pro-
ducer, and taxpayer and by shaping the behaviour
of employees, citizens, communities, other busi-
nesses, and societal institutions.
144
In the UK, the private sector accounts for 60 %
of GDP145 and per capita income and employs
77 % of the workforce
146
. It is responsible for 18 %
of UK territorial Greenhouse Gas (GHG) emissions
on average.
147
It extracts over 100 million tonnes
of natural resources in the mineral and agricultur-
al sectors alone.
148
It uses these resources to sat-
isfy consumption, which has increased nearly 50 %
from 2005 to 2019.
149
At the same time, business practices can exac-
erbate vertical and horizontal inequalities. For
example, a focus on returns to nancial capital can
come at the cost of the returns to labour.
150
Without
regulation, the majority of businesses will contin-
ue to pursue activities that risk undermining envi-
ronmental quality and resilience and undervaluing
workers and the wider community.
In the past, efforts in the UK to compel sustain-
able production focused on closing material cycles,
increasing energy and resource efciency and
decarbonising the energy system. In 2008, the UK
adopted the Climate Change Act, and it is imple-
menting higher standards on efciency and the cir-
cular economy, while growing the renewables sec-
tor. It has improved benchmarks for ESG disclo-
sures
151
, has taxed plastic bags in grocery stores
152
and implemented the UK Trading Systems (UK ETS)
and carbon pricing.
While these measures are moving in the right
direction, they fall short in terms of scope and
speed of change. While the UK has seen a decrease
in carbon emissions in the private sector by 41 %
since 1990
153
, the speed of decarbonisation has to
further accelerate to stay within the 1.5° goal of
the Paris Agreement.
154
The UKs private sector has
made progress in reducing dependency on fossil
fuels, reducing the use of coal by 80 %, gas by 20 %
and oil by 6 % in the last decade
155
, but the pri-
vate sector is still hugely dependent on these fuel
sources. Efciency gains might be realised in one
sector, but they are often offset by an increase in
production on the other.
156
The expectation for businesses to be more
inclusive of social and environmental considera-
tions is growing. Businesses are already feeling
pressure to become more sustainable, primarily
from their competitors, following customers and
governments.
157
However, only 17 % of the current
market is demanding more sustainable products.
158
Despite this, the prominence of the “ESG” agen-
da is growing.
Challenges
Barriers to implementing sustai-
nable and fair business models
From the literature, we identied a series of barri-
ers that limit the development of sustainable and
fair business models:
1.
Short-termism: Institutional investors
are typically unable to sacrice
short-term nance returns in support of
ESG guidelines
159
as they have the duciary
duty to preserve capital and maximise risk
adjusted returns.
Business
34
BusinessBuilding a resilient economy
Content
2. Fiercely competitive market contexts
which create narrow prot incentives
and pressures to compete on cost and
price, driving outsourcing, automation, and
externalisation. These prots are important to
pay for the opportunity costs of the owner, to
service liabilities and attract investors to keep
up with technological progress. Coupled with
the need to scale, the sustainable investment
market is often not large enough to attract big
institutional investors to support the transition
toward sustainability.
160
In markets for goods
and services, for those who cannot differenti
-
ate their product, going against these trends
means their customers would purchase else
-
where and the rm would become unviable.
3. Without standardisation of meas-
urements and labels, investors (and
consumers) cannot compare products against
each other, and sustainability is left as a “nice
to have” instead of a requirement. There is
a lack of common language and inadequate
measurement tools to aid businesses in their
transition towards sustainability.
161
Without
standardisation mechanisms, companies,
investors and consumers have no way to
compare the efforts of respective businesses
which translates to weak incentives for
businesses to change.
4.
Lobbying that pushes for unambitious
regulation and loopholes for busi-
nesses to exploit, potentially exacerbated by
reliance of certain regions on the presence
(and hence employment footprint) of a single
rm or industry (see Policy).
5.
Corporate governance structures and
business models that elevate nancial
over social and environmental interests and
incentivise managers to make decisions
accordingly.
Solutions
Policy options to drive
sustainable business behaviour
As outlined in the chapter on the role of Policy,
governments incentivise or dis-incentivise cer-
tain business behaviour. In order to achieve sus-
tainable business behaviour, there is a need for
changing legal frameworks and for providing
the right incentives and mandating tools, meth-
ods and models that support longer-term visions.
For example, public procurement and tax poli-
cies are key levers to inculcate better distribu-
tion of value shared. Furthermore, regulations,
trade-agreements and standard setting can deter-
mine how environmental impacts are approached
and accounted for. Drawing on our literature review,
we have identied four clusters of policy action:
Shifting Protability
Protability is one of the major drivers that deter-
mine where investments flow and business mod-
els emerge. To change what is protable, govern-
ments can undertake tax (and subsidy) reforms to
encourage companies to better align their activi-
ties with socially and environmentally benecial
outcomes. For example
162
:
Move towards a new taxation paradigm.
Rather than taxing what people value (employ-
ment), policy should tax harmful activities
(environmental damages), increase taxes on
resource use such as Carbon or Resource
taxes
163
, phase out direct and indirect fossil
fuel subsidies
164
and lower taxes on labour.
165
Advance tax collection tactics and promote
international collaboration. The corporate tax
base has steadily been eroded as globalisation
of corporate activities allowed companies to
35
BusinessBuilding a resilient economy
Content
shift home-bases and transfer liabilities to tax
havens.
166
This has exacerbated inequality and
undermined public revenue.
167
One example of
a new tactic to end tax avoidance and evasion
is the OECD / G20 Inclusive Framework on
Base Erosion and Prot-Shifting.
Non-nancial Disclosure,
Reporting and Accountability
Many authors have advocated for an inclusion
of external environmental costs into economic
accounting.
168
As flagged elsewhere in this report,
requiring corporate disclosure, reporting against
clear benchmarks and increased accountability
can move businesses away from a narrow focus on
short-term prot maximisation towards the incor-
poration of wider societal concerns in business
decision making. For example:
Require businesses to include both social
and environmental objectives in their stated
purpose and accounting;
Develop biodiversity labels for nancial prod-
ucts for retail investors to be better informed
on the real impacts of their investments;
Full cost accounting for environmental exter-
nalities to change patterns of use, purchase
and production via more accurate prices;
Establish a common international standard
for calculating carbon content and biodiversity
impacts of goods.
Sustainable Investment
and Innovation
Challenges such as climate change, health and well-
being are complex and interconnected: solving them
requires the inclusion of several different stakehold
-
ers. Businesses need to have access to resourc-
es and partners in order to invest and innovate in
addressing these challenges.
169
For example, prop-
erly targeted and monitored government invest-
ment can provide businesses with access to nance
that underwrites experimentation and innovation for
sustainability.
170
Regulations also matter: to increase the circu-
larity of economies, governments might regulate
for extended producer responsibility (such as via
longer warranties), that encourages better dura-
bility of products, alongside the right to repair and
modularity standards. Creating design require-
ments for products such as the Cradle to Cra-
dle framework
171
and punishing planned obsoles-
cence
172
can increase repair and reuse potential
173
,
while banning waste disposal can compel practic-
es such as food-sharing.
Sustainable Business Models
In the current system, a substantial number of
businesses are congured so that their utmost
goal is to maximise prots for shareholders. This
heightened focus on economic prot and growth is
often counter to the interests of other stakehold-
ers and fails to adopt longer-term time horizons.
Policy can ensure businesses incorporate environ-
mental and social considerations into internal gov-
ernance structures to be accountable for and deliv-
er on a suite of impacts
174, 175
via:
Regulating for legal forms beyond the Public
Limited Company (PLC). The UK, for example,
has a suite of pro-social business models such
as Community Interest Companies, social
enterprise, and cooperatives.
Using incentives (tax breaks, accounting advice,
preferential procurement and so on) that
encourage the uptake of such business models.
36
CitizensBuilding a resilient economy
Content
» The focus on consumer
sovereignty fails to acknowledge
the influence on individual
consumption behaviour of
contextual factors. «
Consumption is also a major factor in rising global
emissions and environmental degradation beyond
planetary boundaries. Considering the entire glob-
al value chain, nutrition, housing and mobility
account for approximately 75 % of lifestyle carbon
footprints.
176
Hotspots include meat and dairy con-
sumption, fossil-fuel-based energy, car use and air
travel. To get on track towards the Paris Agreement
will require immense reductions of carbon foot-
prints by up to 96 % in industrialised countries, in
the next 30 years.
177
Not all people equally contribute to this prob-
lem. Forms of consumption are enormously une-
qual distributed, both between and within coun-
tries. 20 % of the world’s population in the wealth-
iest industrialised countries account for 86 % of
the world’s consumption, while the world’s poorest
20 % account for only 1.3 %.
178
With disposable per
capita income being a major driver of consumption,
the environmental impact of households increases
with income.
179
Policy efforts for sustainability so far have
primarily focused on accelerating technologi-
cal change to make production more sustainable,
by decarbonising energy provision and improving
material and energy efciency (for discussion of
this approach, see Business).
Policy based on the demand side of consump-
tion have thus far had limited success in changing
unsustainable behaviours.
180, 181
This is due to their
basis in the concept of consumer sovereignty i. e.
policies such as information labels about sustain-
able products and price signals.
182
However, this
focus fails to acknowledge the influence on indi-
vidual consumption behaviour of contextual fac-
tors like infrastructures
183
, provisioning systems
184,
185, 186
, inequality
187
, psychological drivers and hab-
its and norms
188
.
Sustainable consumption policy is about influenc-
ing how and what people consume. It is about
providing new sustainable consumption
options and the necessary infrastructures.
decreasing overall consumption levels and
addressing the underlying drivers of increased
consumption.
ensuring that needs satisfaction does not
necessarily rely on material consumption and
income, but also on immaterial goods.
Challenges
Barriers for change towards
sustainable living and drivers
for unsustainable behaviour
Literature outlines two levels of barriers to sustain-
able consumption: social and physical infrastruc-
tures at the structural level and deeply enrooted
habits at the cultural level.
Social and physical
infrastructures
The rst barrier are lock-ins to unsustainable con-
sumption patterns beyond individual control.
These result from
a. existing infrastructures
189, 190,191
,
b. availability of consumption options,
Citizens
37
CitizensBuilding a resilient economy
Content
c. misleading incentives
192, 193, 194
and
d. economic threats.
195
Existing infrastructure in industrialised econo-
mies make it difcult to consume in a sustaina-
ble way. There is limited access to sustainable
alternatives for high environmental impact hous-
ing, energy, mobility and nutrition, everyday con-
sumer products, working environments and social
integration. In many sectors, sustainable alter-
natives are simply not available (e. g. the IT sec-
tor) or are not affordable for everyone (e. g. organ-
ic food, clothing and material for housing). Further,
misleading incentive structures promote unsus-
tainable consumption patterns. Subsidies for fos-
sil fuels, large-scale industrial agriculture, or tax-
free kerosene distort prices for consumers, thus
encouraging unsustainable consumption.
Another barrier is efciency consumption, when
consumption is presented as an offer you can’t
refuse
196
. Owning certain products is required to
actively participate in society, increase time ef-
ciency and become employed. Examples include
washing machines, cars and mobile phones. Ones
ability to drive to work, communicate efcient-
ly and have sufcient time for a full working week
depends on access to goods and services and on
whether employers and colleagues expect one to
have this access. In this case, consumption is not
a choice, but becomes a necessity.
Habits
In todays society, consumption serves impor-
tant social and psychological functions that pose
a cultural barrier to sustainable consumption. The
cultural relevance of consumption in high-income
societies associates higher levels of consumption
with improvements in wellbeing, beyond the meet-
ing of basic needs. For example, the term “status
consumption” describes how people manifest their
role in society by owning goods that offer recogni-
tion. In addition, alternative means for needs sat-
isfaction are limited, e. g. recognition via stronger
and meaningful relationships.
Solutions
Policy actions to enable
sustainable living
Policymaking has the tools to effectively change
social infrastructures and set incentives for cultur-
al change, the two mutually reinforcing drivers of
unsustainable consumption. Addressing both lev-
els of barriers is crucial to initiate change. To effec-
tively tackle unsustainable consumption, litera-
ture describes three levels that policy can address:
What people (can) consume (incentives, consump-
tion options and infrastructures), how they con-
sume (behaviour and culture) and the creation of
more equal consumption opportunities (affordabil-
ity and income inequality).
Sustainable consumption
alternatives
In a society with diverse values, sustainable prod-
ucts must be cheaper than unsustainable alterna-
tives, for sustainable consumption to become the
norm. This requires effective incentives or regula-
tions, as discussed in the Business chapter. Mar-
ket prices must integrate true environmental and
social costs, e. g. via the introduction of taxes on
carbon emissions
197, 198, 199
or stricter waste incin-
eration laws
200
.
38
CitizensBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Of particular importance is decreasing direct and
indirect prices for basic needs and services like
mobility, nutrition, housing and increasing prices
for luxury goods, to influence what is consumed.
Likewise, regulation can promote more sustain-
able consumptions. For transport options, this
means lowering costs of public transport, abolish-
ing VAT for rail travel, introducing a tax on kerosene,
setting incentives for car-free travel and commut-
ing, setting speed limits for cars or including the
transport sector in the emissions trading scheme
to reflect the right prices for transport.
201
For the
working environment, this can mean introducing
one Veggie Day a week for canteen food or nan-
cially supporting alternatives to commuting to work
by car.
202
With regards to nutrition, recommended
policy actions include price incentives to substi-
tute dairy products and red meat with plant-based
options and raising taxes on meat.
203
Concerning
housing, recommended policy actions include pro-
gressive estate taxes on e. g. living space, to avoid
efciency improvements being negated by increas-
es in living space. Status consumption beyond what
people really need can be discouraged through
taxes on luxury goods
204
, or higher taxes on prod-
ucts beyond basic needs.
205
Prices alone are not sufcient for transitioning
towards more sustainable production and con-
sumption systems. For incentives to reach their
full potential, policy must promote better availabil-
ity of sustainable alternatives, reduce transaction
costs and make unsustainable options unavailable.
Exemplary policy options include the introduction
of low-emission transport infrastructure such as
bike lanes or public transport, target values for bike
sharing
206, 207
and good pedestrian infrastructure in
all trafc areas. Further, policy can direct innova-
tion where it reduces transaction costs of sustaina-
ble services, making sustainable consumption eas-
ier and more comfortable. An example is the sim-
plication of cross-border train bookings. Lastly,
policy regulation is needed to limit non-sustaina-
ble products and services such as domestic flights,
plastic bags or meat products in canteens.
208
Policy can strengthen local and sustainable
consumption and thereby lower transport emis-
sions, while establishing and diversifying local
working opportunities. A wide variety of policy
options include nancial incentives for local pro-
duction, regional business development focused
on ecological, non-intensive small-scale agricul-
ture, community-supported agriculture, strength-
ening of local eco-tourism
209
, price incentives to
consume regional, seasonal food, as well as reg-
ulations that make the implementation of comple-
mentary local currencies possible.
210, 211
Infrastructures for sufciency
Along with “what” people consume, great poten-
tial lies in changing “how” people consume.
Rather than replacing a product with a sustaina-
ble alternative, the “howit is about reflecting on
the necessity of using and owning certain servic-
es and goods and move towards sufciency. Suf-
ciency means to identify new ways of needs sat-
isfaction beyond material consumption, reducing
overall consumption levels and creating structures
for social integration that do not rely on material
consumption.
To ensure this, infrastructures that allow a dif-
ferent form of consumption and working life are
required e. g. reducing working hours
212
, enabling
sabbaticals
213
or working from home. Such chang-
es have the potential to offer opportunities to con-
sume differently, as they provide more time for
more sustainable, time-intensive activities.
» Prices alone are not sufcient 
for transitioning towards more
sustainable production and
consumption systems.«
39
CitizensBuilding a resilient economy
Content
For example, this additional time can be used to
repair products. Demand-side policies can make
this easier, e. g. by supporting the implementa-
tion of repair cafés that increase awareness of and
care for product durability and support a shift away
from a “throw-away” mentality.
214, 215
A sharing economy would make people recon-
sider which goods really needed to be owned and
which can be substituted by services. Well-known
examples of a sharing economy include car shar-
ing, bike sharing and the introduction of neighbour-
hood sharing systems for goods people rarely use,
like special toolkits.
216, 217
The development of new ways of housing has
the potential to reduce the living space and the
associated energy demands for heating i.e. model
projects for alternative forms of housing such as
multi-generation houses and the construction of
overall smaller living spaces.
218
A different form of nutrition can be incentivised
through the creation of community-supported agri-
culture and community gardening, creating new
communal spaces and raising awareness of and
demand for the consumption of seasonal food.
219, 220
Affordability and fairness
Literature stresses that addressing inequality is
a necessary precondition to effectively changing
the “what” and “howof peoples consumption.
Therefore, policies that ensure people are able,
nancially and socially, to satisfy their basic needs
and participate in society are necessary to enable
sustainable consumption. Such policies include
establishing minimum and maximum income lev-
els
221, 222
, a universal basic income (monetary
and non-monetary)
223, 224
, and / or wage tax cuts
for low-income households ( Power).
225
Further
measures include providing equal access to sus-
tainable goods and services through providing
vouchers for rail travel, regional food and sustain-
able housing for low-income households. Universal
access to health care and education
226
, increases
in energy efciency of buildings and housing
227, 228
,
and free public transport can play a crucial role in
creating more sustainable consumption.
40
Interim conclusion Building a resilient economy
Content
This section has shown the amount of possible
changes mentioned in the literature and made
clear that economic behaviour is not set in stone.
Be it politics, nance, business or citizens, behav-
iour is always the result of existing political deci-
sions, legislation and systems. Therefore, to nd
the way to a resilient economy, it is necessary to
change the underlying systemic factors.
As illustrated in the previous chapters, there
are a number of constraining forces that hinder
change. They prevent people from changing their
consumption, investment, or political decisions.
Figure 1 summarises these factors.
However, these constraining forces can be
countered by the enabling forces of change sum-
marised in the previous sections, as depicted in
Figure 1. The enabling forces are a summary of
the political intervention options. They show start-
ing points for alternative policies that – if cast into
political legislation – can free the actors from their
cages and enable them to move towards a resilient
economy in their respective elds (politics, nance,
business, or consumption).
While some required changes may be hard to
swallow, policies in each of the elds of action are
strongly interconnected. They only develop their
full effectiveness when they are applied at different
points (see Box A systemic change mindset” ).
Their interplay can generate many co-benets.
Investments into green sectors include job oppor-
tunities in the renewable energy sector, the cir-
cular economy or care, cultural and crafting sec-
tors. Improvements in environmental quality and
equality could have positive effects on health and
wellbeing. Providing public expenditures to x the
harm created by the current economic system may
increase economic resilience and provide resourc-
es to reduce poverty. Rethinking how we consume
can leave people with more time for their relation-
ships, families, and friends.
In the next chapter we will discuss eight of these
proposals in detail and show how they reinforce
each other.
Interim conclusion
Thinking about and engaging
in systemic change
41
Interim conclusion Building a resilient economy
Content
A systemic change mindset
It is not easy to nd and prioritise systemic change among the options
presented here. Prioritisation requires changes in how policymakers think.
Science and policymakers often use mechanical images to guide thinking on
solutions: leverage points, gear wheels or levers, which encourages a focus
on the most important lever, the one size ts all” solution. However, reality is
too complex to be captured in mechanical terms and linear pictures. Solutions
capable of creating systems change require thinking in terms of a network.
In fact, the network metaphor is ideal for systems: if one pulls on one point,
the tension to connected points will increase. If environmental taxes are
implemented, their impact will be limited by distributive implications. If policy
wants to use other indicators and goals, the realisation will be limited by the
power of those actors who prot most from economic growth as a policy goal.
Policymaking for systemic change is not about nding the right lever, for there
is never a “most important point” to address. It is about nding the most
connected node points that lock-in the current behaviour patterns of policy,
business, nance, and citizens. Only a package of policies that targets several
points of the network simultaneously can direct the system towards a more
sustainable state. The second part of this report presents one option for
such a package.
Figure 1: Enablers and barriers towards a resilient economy.
Policy and
governments
Finance
Short
termism
Power
Imbalances
Culture and
policy
frameworks
Mandates
and legal
interpretations
Extractive
Economy
Multidimensional
indicators,
monitoring
capacity, and
legal frameworks
Sustainable
consumption
alternatives
Shifting
protability
Non-nancial
disclosure,
reporting and
accountability
Sustainable
investment and
innovation
Sustainable
business models
Infrastructures
for sufciency
Affordability
and fairness
Corporate
governance
Lobbying
Social and
physical
infrastructures
Incentive
structures
Short-term
horizons
Standardisation
of measurements
Habits
Market
competition
Compartmentalized
governance and
short-term focused
political value
systems
Resilient Economy
Resilient Economy
Resilient Economy
Resilient Economy
Business
Citizens
Limiting
power and
empowerment
for change
Power
imbalances
Fiscal policy
and growth
independence
Metrics for the
long-term
Lack of
metrics
Content
44
Policy and governments
Constraining forces
Compartmentalized governance
and short-term focused political
value systems
Non-binding international agreements
Short-term oriented political value systems
and governance processes
Economic mindsets in public institutions
Short-termism due to election cycles
Power imbalances
High influence of few businesses on policy
High concentration of turnover and jobs
Enabling forces
Multidimensional indicators,
monitoring capacity, and
legal frameworks
Integrate multi-dimensional indicators into
the whole policy cycle
Increase capacities for systems thinking
Promote long-term thinking trough legal frameworks
Fiscal policy and
growth independence
Decouple economic stability from
economic growth
Change scal assessment frameworks
Create scal space for investments in
green infrastructure, health and education
Introduce taxes on environmentally and
socially harmful activities
Combat tax avoidance and evasion
Limiting power and empowerment
for change
Redistribute wealth and incomes
Break the power of monopolies and trusts
Change ownership structures of businesses
Involve citizen assemblies into policy design
Extend policy coherence across national
borders
Finance
Constraining forces
Short termism
Time horizons rarely extend beyond the
business cycle
Risk aversion of institutional investors
Narrow legal interpretation of duciary duties
by institutional investors
Lack of metrics
Lack of standardisation and comparability of ESG data
Culture and policy frameworks
Value systems focused on short termism
and monetary prot
Lack of clear incentives and direction by
overall policy frameworks and regulators
Enabling forces
Mandates and legal interpretations
Green mandates of central banks and
regulators
Account for nature-related risks
Clarify non-nancial dimensions of duciary duties
Metrics for the long-term
Introduce common standards for
environmental metrics
Mandatory disclosure and publicly backed
assessment methodologies
Content
45
Business
Constraining forces
Short-term horizons
Narrow focus on short-term
Market competition
Pressures to compete and innovate
Standardisation of measurements
Lack of standardised sustainability
measurements
Lobbying
Influential lobbying for weak regulation
and loopholes
Incentive structures
Lack of enforcement of policies
Corporate governance
Prioritisation of nancial over social and
environmental interests
Enabling forces
Shifting protability
Shift protability from environmentally
harmful activities to activities that increase
planetary health and wellbeing
Impose limits on resource use and carbon emissions
Non-nancial disclosure, reporting
and accountability
Introduce full cost accounting
Establish standards for calculating climate
and biodiversity impacts
Sustainable investment and innovation
Promote business experimentation and
innovation for sustainability
Introduce stronger design and durability requirements
Sustainable business models
Promote social business types beyond Public
Limited Companies
Citizens
Constraining forces
Social and physical infrastructures
Existing resource-intensive infrastructures
Lack of sustainable and affordable
consumption alternatives
Misleading incentive structures
Need for time-efciency increasing
consumption
Habits
Cultural signicance of consumption
Lack of alternative ways for immaterial needs satisfac-
tion
Enabling forces
Sustainabe consumption alternatives
Price environmental and social costs
Subsidise basic necessities and sustainable mobility,
nutrition, and housing
Increase investments in green infrastructure
Create disincentives for unsustainable
products and services and luxury goods
Strengthen local and fair economies
Infrastructures for sufciency
Create infrastructure for non-material
consumption
Reduce working time
Promote repairing, reusing and recycling
of goods
Promote the sharing economy
Reduce unsustainable consumption
Affordability and fairness
Support low-income households with
payments or vouchers
Ensure universal access to basic goods services
Part 2
Policy options for the
UK to move towards a
resilient economy
This chapter presents a consistent set of eight policies for the
UK that are feasible and topical, suitable to support COVID-19
recovery and can deliver systemic change.
48
IntroductionBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Building on the literature review and a compre-
hensive understanding of what systemic change
requires, the aim of this chapter is to present a set
of policies that the UK can use to pave the way to
a resilient economy. Setting priorities was the big-
gest challenge. To do this, the following questions
were raised:
Focus: How can the number of policies be
kept to a minimum?
Synergies: Which policies are suited for
achieving several goals simultaneously?
Consistency: How can a set of policies appear
consistent, so negative effects of certain
policies are compensated by others?
Sequencing: In what order should policies
be implemented, so that steps taken today
facilitate desired changes thereafter?
Prioritisation is always accompanied by a high
degree of normative evaluation. In our case, four
experts evaluated the systemic change poli-
cies proposed in the literature against the crite-
ria of feasibility in the UK, COVID-19 compatibil-
ity and transformative potential (see Method-
ology). The list provided here is therefore not to
be understood as the only solution. Rather, it is to
be understood as an invitation to discuss what is
needed and single proposals can be supplemented,
adapted or rejected. The selection of policies and
the intervention clusters addressed by these poli-
cies are shown in Table 2.
Policies are listed in order of increasing trans-
formative impact, whereas proposals at the top
make the implementation of proposals at the bot-
tom more likely. As an example, if investments
are channelled into sustainable business models
through a Wellbeing Budget or green credit guid-
ance, the adjustment cost of introducing resource
caps will be much smaller. Alternatives will already
be in place that provide jobs and infrastructure,
ensuring higher levels of wellbeing.
While this list sets out what the UK can do, the rec-
ommendations for transformative policies are like-
ly to be applicable around the world.
Introduction
Table 2: Prioritised policy proposals for the UK with increasing transformative impact in a sequenced order and targeted
intervention clusters
49
IntroductionBuilding a resilient economy
Content
49
Multidimensional Indicators, monitoring
capacity, and legal frameworks
Fiscal policy and growth
independence
Limiting power and
empowerment for change
Mandates and legal
interpretations
Metrics for the long-term
Shifting Protability
Sustainable investments and innovation
Non-nancial disclosure,
reporting and accountability
Sustainable business models
Sustainable consumption
alternatives
Sufciency
Affordability and fairness
Policy
1. Wellbeing Budget
2. Modernising UK’s scal
rules
3. New National Investment
Authority
4. Mandatory nancial
risk assessments
and disclosure
5. Green Credit Guidance
6. Land value tax
7. Resource caps and
biodiversity
8. Environmental border tax
50
Rationale behind this prioritisationBuilding a resilient economy
Content
First, let us briefly elaborate on our rationale behind
this prioritisation of policies and present the argu-
ments for their selection along the three selection
criteria: feasibility & topicality, COVID-19 suita-
bility, and transformative potential. Generally our
approach is based on the idea that in the short
term, investments need to be targeted towards a
sustainable and resilient economy, to drive down
costs and ensure that a carbon-neutral and circu-
lar economy does not lead to more exclusion and
social polarisation.
The policies that encourage greater public invest-
ment will necessarily need to operate within an
environment of much more progressive taxation.
After all, taxation and sovereign debt issuance are
the two main ways for the public sector to raise
nance and invest in the economy. But the current
tax regime in the UK creates adverse outcomes
with individuals paying a lot more tax on their
income than those that merely inherit wealth or
see gains on their capital investment. While redis-
tribution through tax has been an ask of progres-
sive movements for a long time, it inherently does
not do much to alter the rent-seeking behaviour
and nancialisation of the markets. Taxing wealth,
capital gains, polluters and nancial transactions,
for instance, are all important but they do not per
se generate positive outcomes for the environment,
particularly if governments continue to see tax as a
way to reduce very high public decits.
The policies proposed here are tuned towards the
investment narrative which we believe to be the
comparably more effective route to transforming
the economy and shaping markets in the process.
An objective or mission oriented approach to
investment led by public money can signal and
drive the markets to deliver the environmental and
social outcomes we urgently need.
If sustainable behaviour is to become the norm
rather than the exception, systemic change
requires changing the rules of the entire market.
Due to the lack of environmental taxes and state
support, only a selection of sustainable business-
es is protable. Moreover, the missing environ-
mental taxes allow a tremendous externalisation
of environmental and social costs and thus subsi-
dise carbon- and resource intensive business mod-
els. Therefore, in the current economic framework,
sustainable business models will not attract the
scale of investment that is required to ensure they
are competitive and can survive in the long term.
Sustainable businesses under current conditions
might be able to compete within a certain niche,
but not in a competitive mass market.
Addressing protability and providing guidance
for investments holds the potential to shift com-
petitive advantages, innovation and technological
change. Sustainable business models would then
be the outcome, rather than the driver of system-
ic change. Sustainable businesses in niche areas
are nonetheless important examples of a differ-
ent model of operation that could encourage pol-
icymakers to implement stricter regulations. This
approach assumes that predominantly soft stand-
ards do not directly ensure that companies inter-
nalise all their external costs and face huge nanc-
ing barriers to transform their business models.
Table 2 provides an overview how each of the
selected policies contributes to systemic change.
In Table 3 the arguments for the selection are
summarised in more detail.
Rationale behind this prioritisation
Policy
Feasibility & Topicality COVID-19 compatibility Transformative potential
1. Wellbeing Budget
Successful existing exam-
ples in other countries;
need to use new state
funds properly
Necessity to reduce
government spending in the
future in order to decrease
government debt;
Strengthening of systemic
thinking in scal policy;
steering of investments
in sectors of the resilient
and sustainable economy;
improved accounting of
long-term policy goals;
support of sustainable
business models and
lifestyles; making short-
term prot maximisation at
the expense of the general
public more difcult and
strengthening sustainable
sectors shifts power
relations
2. Modernising
UK’s scal rules
Existing successful exam-
ples in other countries;
paradigm shift away from
the primacy of monetary
policy; low interest rates for
government bonds
Lesson from the suspension
of existing scal rules; new
approach to government
decits without increasing
future risks
Closing the existing
investment gap for the
achievement of climate and
environmental goals; better
mapping of long-term goals
in scal policy; avoidance
of future costs from climate
change
3. New National Investment
Authority
Existing successful exam-
ples in other countries;
need to properly manage
new state investments in
terms of long-term goals
Effective approach to use
new state funds
Orientation of scal policy
towards long-term goals;
steering of investments
in sectors of the resilient
and sustainable economy;
support for sustainable
business models and
lifestyles; making short-
term prot maximisation at
the expense of the general
public more difcult shifts
power relations
4. Mandatory nancial
risk assessments and
disclosure
No fundamentally new
practice; but stronger
enforcement of existing
practices; reduction of
future crises and credit
default risks
Banks are looking for new
investment opportunities
Steering of investments
in sectors of the resilient
and sustainable economy;
Has indirect effect on the
transparency of corporate
models and value chains;
Difculty of short-term
prot maximisation at the
expense of the general
public shifts power
relations
Table 3: Arguments for the selection of policies based on the three dimensions feasibility & topicality, COVID-19 suitability
and transformative potential. Table is continued on the next page  
51
Rationale behind this prioritisationBuilding a resilient economy
Content
51
Policy
Feasibility & Topicality COVID-19 compatibility Transformative potential
5. Green Credit Guidance
Discursive shift away from
price stability as the sole
task of central banks;
pre-pandemic commitment
to review monetary policy
frameworks; existing exam-
ples in other countries
Reduction of future crises;
need for new investment
impulses from central
banks
Steering of investments
in sectors of the resilient
and sustainable economy;
making short-term prot
maximisation at the
expense of the general
public more difcult shifts
the balance of power
6. Land value tax
Existing examples in other
countries; need to generate
new government revenue
to nance debt; prevailing
high levels of wealth and
income inequality
Tax with great revenue
potential and at the same
time hardly any negative
welfare effects compared
to other taxes
Reduce privatisation of
prots promoted by public
investment; reduce one
of the main drivers of
inequality; nance a just
transition;
7. Resource caps and
biodiversity
Existing experience
with carbon taxes;
increasing perception of
the biodiversity crisis; lack
of decoupling of resource
consumption and economic
growth
Generation of new govern-
ment revenues to nance
the recovery measures
Setting hard limits for
resource-intensive busi-
ness models and lifestyles;
promotes sufciency;
Has indirect effect on the
transparency of corporate
models and value chains
8. Environmental border tax
Discussions about a Border
Carbon Tax on EU level
need to preserve domestic
jobs and ensure interna-
tional competitiveness
steering investments in
sectors of the circular econ-
omy in the UK and abroad;
global precedent for a new
way of dealing with carbon
and biodiversity leakage
instead of exceptions;
Has indirect effect on the
transparency of corporate
models and value chains
Table 3: Arguments for the selection of policies based on the three dimensions feasibility & topicality, COVID-19 suitability
and transformative potential
52
Rationale behind this prioritisationBuilding a resilient economy
Content
54
A Wellbeing Budget for the UKBuilding a resilient economy
Content
» A Wellbeing Budget seeks to elevate goals and
activities aligned with what people and planet need. «
Multidimensional indicators, monitoring capacity, and legal
frameworks p. 25
Fiscal policy and growth independence p. 26
Limiting power and empowerment for change p. 27 Sustainable
consumption alternatives p. 37
Affordability and fairness p. 39
While governments do consider a wide range of impacts, for example via equality
impact assessments or environmental impact assessments, spending does not
necessarily respond to the needs, and Gross Domestic Product retains its primacy as
the default measure of economic success and, invariably, of government prowess.
A Wellbeing Budget seeks to elevate goals and activities aligned with what people
and planet need. It promotes the attainment of environmental and socio-economic
outcomes by prioritising and redirecting government spending to initiatives that
deliver on goals such as greater equality and environmental benet.
Government departments would need to demonstrate their positive impact on a set
of politically agreed upon headline measures in order to receive budget allocations, or
a proportion thereof. A Wellbeing Budget approach increases the capacity of policy to
solve today’s most complex and urgent challenges by:
1. Taking a systems perspective and recognising interdependencies between
government activities by using a dashboard of indicators to assess the multi-
dimensional wellbeing of current and future generations. This dashboard would
better capture environmental and social impact than targets such as Gross
Domestic Product, by better illuminating wider goals and trade-offs. The elevation
of these goals protects them against being swept aside in favour of narrow short-
term nancial priorities.
2. Encouraging cross-departmental collaboration to recognise and harness scal
savings accruing beyond one departmental silo and beyond single spending
cycles.
A Wellbeing Budget for the UK
Associated clusters
1.
55
A Wellbeing Budget for the UKBuilding a resilient economy
Content
A Wellbeing Budget for the UK
3. Promoting precautionary policymaking that mitigates negative long-term out-
comes. Currently, substantial amounts of public funds are deployed in attending
to the harm caused by inequality and environmental depletion e. g. tax credits
to top up low wages and treatment of avoidable stress and anxiety; repairs to
infrastructure and treatment for health ailments caused by polluted air. Yet, as
the Dasgupta’s review interim report states, “it is more cost-effective to maintain
an ecosystem than it is to degrade and then restore it: conservation trumps rest-
oration”.
229
A Wellbeing Budget reduces long-term scal costs.
A Wellbeing Budget has been described by respondents to our survey as a “game
changer … that could transform decision making”; “likely to be well received and to be
transformative”; “[it reaches] the deeper levels of the problem” and has the possibility to
extend impact beyond the UK by setting “a precedent for other countries”. A strategy to
implement a Wellbeing Budget could include the following steps:
1. Build public demand via cross-political, cross-institutional and cross-sectoral
coalitions for a Wellbeing Budget, ideally with several high-prole champions
within and beyond politics and inclusive participatory processes to determine
priority goals.
2. Build capacity within government agencies to invest long-term, link spending to
various ONS measures (and commission new measures if necessary) and incenti-
vise cross-departmental collaboration.
3. Introduce a pilot for wellbeing-led spending in the 2021 budget.
4. Communicate success stories and scale up momentum for a bolder and more
comprehensive 2022 Wellbeing Budget.
Inspirations
The 2019 New Zealand Wellbeing Budget (using the Treasurys Living Standards
Framework) with low carbon economy as one of its ve priorities, led to considerable
spending aimed at mitigating
230
– rather than ameliorating – environmental harm.
The Welsh Government’s Wellbeing of Future Generations Act (with budget scrutiny
carried out by the independent Future Generations Commissioner).
Bhutan’s response to inequalities in wellbeing as revealed by its Gross National
Happiness surveys, focuses on the root causes of lower wellbeing amongst certain
population groups, such as women or rural communities.
56
A Wellbeing Budget for the UKBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Enablers and barriers
Enablers:
Emerging evidence of scal savings and tangible quality of life improvements.
Strong leadership to champion the approach.
Cross-party support to avoid it becoming a political tool.
Deployment and building of Treasury capacities to support its implementation,
including navigating trade-offs and undertaking system-wide macroeconomic
modelling.
Barriers:
Balancing immediate acute needs while simultaneously investing in
upstream preventative activities
A lack of tools and processes to capture the benets and savings of
preventative spending
Resources required to properly and authentically involve the public in
determining priority goals
Persistence of GDP growth as central element in conceptions of economic and
political success.
Windows of opportunity
The shift in priorities sparked by the COVID-19 crisis and the enormous scale
of government spending and intervention in response constitute an opening of
political space to transformative ideas hitherto dismissed as impossible. The various
emergency budget statements and spending reviews already underway are junctures
where new ways of undertaking government spending could be adopted. As the UK
charts its post-Brexit economy in 2021 and seeks to make good on its “levelling up
agenda, it will host the (delayed) COP26 where it will be seeking to tell a positive
story about the UK’s role in the world – all of which will be aided by a Wellbeing
Budget.
57
A Wellbeing Budget for the UKBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Relevant stakeholders
Media attention will also be important in helping to build support: something as
process-heavy as a Wellbeing Budget is potentially challenging from a public-facing
campaigning perspective. It would need to be framed in compelling, accessible
impact-focused messaging. This challenge could be offset by the potential for
unusual cross-party political alliances and a broad coalition of the willing amongst
civil society as just set out. Moreover,
The APPG on Wellbeing Economics, APPG on Limits to Growth, and the
APPG on Inclusive Growth can build parliamentary buy in.
The Wellbeing Economy Governments partnership can help share practical
experience from around the world.
The What Works Centre for Wellbeing, the Committee on Climate Change, ICAEW
and other scholars can support the evidence base and advise on processes.
Social justice and environmental NGOs and think tanks can build the public
demand – for example the New Economics Foundation, The Equality Trust,
the Green Alliance, IPPR, the Carnegie Trust, the Early Intervention Foundation,
and education, nursing and police unions.
Globally, networks such as WEAll, the Club of Rome, and Club de Madrid can bring
together civil society, scholars, and former heads of state willing to support the
adoption of a Wellbeing Budget.
Associated clusters
58
Modernising UK’s Fiscal RulesBuilding a resilient economy
Content
» The UK can address the investment gaps to meet net zero
emissions by 2050 by enhancing scal space, i. e. its scope 
for greater public borrowing. «
Fiscal policy and growth independence p. 26 Limiting power
and empowerment for change p. 27
Sustainable investments and
innovation p. 35
Affordability and fairness p. 39
Presence of several market failures has resulted in systematic underinvestment in
the low carbon transition and biodiversity conservation. A mix of public investment
and regulation across other sectors of the economy will be essential in driving
a green transition. The Committee on Climate Change estimates a total resource
cost to achieving net zero emissions of between 1–2 % of GDP per year on average
by 2050 – between £ 20 billion and £ 40 billion in 2019/20 terms.
231
An analysis by
Greenpeace and other civil society groups estimate a total additional annual public
investment of £ 25 billion in meeting net zero emissions and addressing the bio diver-
sity crisis.
232
The UK can address these investment gaps by enhancing scal space, i. e. its scope
for greater public borrowing. Fiscal space is underpinned by scal rules that dene
the limits to measures available to scal institutions, like the Treasury, to manage
headwinds facing the economy. They include, for instance, relatively arbitrary rules on
limiting public borrowing to 3 % of GDP or setting targets for balancing current public
spending, which severely limit governments’ ability to appropriately respond to crises.
COVID-19 has prompted the UK government to relax scal rules. France has since
opposed a return to the stability pact and the 3 % decit rule. As monetary policy has
reached certain limits, with interest rates having been at a historical low over the last
decade, the COVID-19 crisis has shown that monetary policy must be complemented
with scal policy to deal with the crisis.
There are numerous reasons to sustain changes in scal rules to prevent future costs
from climate change or biodiversity loss. To do so, the Treasury could:
Modernising UK’s Fiscal Rules2.
59
Modernising UK’s Fiscal RulesBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Modernising UK’s Fiscal Rules
1. Develop a new framework for regularly assessing, measuring and forecasting
safe limits to scal space, and thereby, public investments.
2. Support politicians to make an informed decision on the best combination of scal
intervention or scal prudence at a given point in time and the appropriate size
of preventative spending.
3. Enforce a Resilience Fiscal Rule, requiring all government spending to be aligned
with maximising economic resilience, rather than mere short-time economic stabi-
lisation. Such a rule would also need to work alongside a new, more sophisticated
set of indicators of and targets for “scal space, to replace the current narrow
targets for public debt / borrowing.
Inspirations
The role of state banks like KfW in Germany providing patient capital and supporting
low yielding projects like energy efciency is well established. Thanks to its
structure, the KfW is able to borrow capital without burdening the State’s decit or
the government’s scal rules. Outside Europe, Japan has been a leader in public
R&D investments over the last two decades, while the China Development Bank has
offered patient capital to help fledgling industries to catch up with competitors.
Public investment has also often been necessary alongside regulation to address
failures such as the signicant regional disparity of low carbon infrastructure and its
associated benets, lack of private investment in regenerative agricultural practices,
peatland restoration or smart meter rollouts, to name a few.
Enablers and barriers
Enablers:
The prevailing environment for interest rates and the UK’s possession of a
sovereign currency allow it to borrow considerably higher amounts of resources.
The flexing of scal rules in response to the COVID-19 crisis is forcing the
government to not just drop the pursuit of austerity altogether, but also to explore
the balance between scal prudence and intervention.
Barriers:
An inflexible approach to scal prudence can limit the pace of the transition that
climate science demands and thereby risk the long-term stability of public budgets.
60
Modernising UK’s Fiscal RulesBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Windows of opportunity
The Conservative government’s levelling up agenda remains a top priority and the
government has already indicated that it will not pursue any form of austerity, but
instead invest and grow its way out of the current crisis. This commitment offers an
opportune moment for rethinking scal policy. The Treasury is currently undertaking
a review of the scal rules’ framework, which is due to report in Autumn at the same
time as the Spending Review. As part of the review, the Treasury is exploring the
need for strengthening the scal framework to better mitigate long-term risks and
shocks, including those related to the environment and climate change. Also, the
general mainstream media discourse is shifting towards a wider acceptance of state
intervention in supporting the economy.
233
Relevant stakeholders
Specic low carbon sectors where UK public investment can trigger global supply
chains and induce similar behaviour across other economies, compounding
the benets of domestic action. These include investments in electric vehicles,
hydrogen production, carbon capture, low carbon heating technologies and other
nature-based climate solutions.
The “Left behind” economies of Northern UK, which bear promising potential for
employment that is built on low carbon infrastructure and services.
234
Influential right wing think tank Policy Exchange, which has recently called for
a “credible scal activism” while ditching more orthodox neoclassical economic
approaches
235
.
Organisations under the banner of “Build Back Better” that are calling for
greater flexibility from the government on its scal rules and for spending on
green infrastructure.
A few Conservative MPs from key northern and midland constituencies who are
calling for signicant investment in local green infrastructure and jobs, driven by
a national level public investment vehicle.
61
A New National Investment AuthorityBuilding a resilient economy
Content
» The sustainability objectives require a state-led nancing 
model that meets the need for patient capital while
addressing short-termism in the nancial markets. «
Fiscal policy and growth independence p. 26 Shifting
profitability p. 34
Sustainable investments and innovation p. 35
Sustainable business models p. 35
Sustainable consumption alterna-
tives p. 37
Affordability and fairness p. 39
Policy and regulation are critical but remain, in themselves, inadequate to drive
change at the scale demanded by science. Thus, they also put at risk the long-term
stability of the UK’s public budget. Where perceived risks to private capital are higher,
like regenerative agriculture or large-scale retrotting of homes, much needed
investment has been hard to come by. Initial annual public investment estimates
range from 1–2 % of GDP to achieve net zero and nature conservation targets. These
need to be balanced alongside public spending on innovation and commercialisation
of new low carbon solutions and processes. The high investment needs to achieve
net zero, ecosystems recovery and wider sustainable development goals require a
state-led nancing model that meets the need for patient capital while addressing
short-termism in the nancial markets.
236
A National Investment Authority (NIA) can
serve this purpose by:
1. Channelling public investment towards the objective of a sustainable economy
to help achieve the environmental and recovery objectives.
2. Systematically identifying market failures across the economy, not only with the
aim of xing them, but also to shape the market more deliberately in service
of broader societal benets.
A New National
Investment Authority
Associated clusters
3.
62
A New National Investment AuthorityBuilding a resilient economy
Content
3. Coordinating with the Treasury and the Bank of England on how to allow greater
public borrowing alongside modernising the UK’s Fiscal rules.
4. Taking a twin role of direct infrastructure investment through grants, loans,
guarantees etc. alongside the role of private equity rms that attract private
capital into public infrastructure investment funds that the NIA would hold.
237
Inspirations
In countries that have achieved high degrees of green innovations, the State has
often supplied the patient strategic nance that the private sector was unwilling
to provide.
238
Central governments in such countries have actively shaped new
technological and industrial landscapes by acting as an investor of rst resort, not
simply as lender of last resort.
In many countries patient strategic nance is increasingly coming from national
investment banks (NIBs). Germany, China, Brazil are a few clear examples
where state-driven investment strategies have been effective to achieve specic
mission-led outcomes.
The European Investment Bank is another example that recently announced the
termination of its lending to fossil fuel energy projects and a commitment to invest
1 trillion on climate and environmental projects by 2030.
239
Enablers and barriers
Enablers:
Public investment authorities like the Green Investment Bank, albeit with
considerable limitations, have established a precedent in the UK on how public
capital can direct low carbon development.
The current crisis of COVID-19 and the resulting ballooning of public borrowing
hasn’t yielded calls for austerity, but instead a desire to grow our way out of the
recession within the context of lowest central bank interest rates and negative
yield rates for government debt.
63
A New National Investment AuthorityBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Barriers:
Designing a bank to invest in specic low carbon or green projects with the mere
purpose of crowding in private capital, as was the case with the GIB, signicantly
limits the scope of investments and remains a major barrier for creating an
effective investment authority.
Windows of opportunity
UK’s Energy Minister, Kwasi Kwarteng, suggested that the government was
seriously considering a new investment authority, a green investment bank 2.0,
highlighting the role that KfW has played so far in Germany.
240
Hundreds of local authorities across the UK, having declared a climate emergency,
are poised to drive a green recovery. But a decade of austerity cuts has left them
signicantly depleted of resources. A central government-led investment program
that pursues broad outcomes through a series of region-specic strategies will
be essential.
Relevant stakeholders
Hundreds of local authorities across the UK who have a major interest in estab-
lishing an NIA and who have recently called for a new Net Zero Development Bank
to accelerate private capital in local energy schemes that often face signicant
scal barriers.
241
Several of those that have campaigned for the green investment
bank between 2009–2012 are now calling for a similar institution to be set up.
242
The RSAs Food, Farming and Countryside Commission who, in its recent report,
recommended the creation of a National Agroecology Development Bank.
243
A broad range of civil society groups, in partnership with local authorities and
businesses, is collectively arguing for a more purpose- and mission-driven public
investment authority to tackle the triple crises of climate change, biodiversity loss
and economic inequality.
Associated clusters
64
Mandatory Financial Risk Assessments and DisclosureBuilding a resilient economy
Content
» For environmental risks, the Prudential Regulation
Authority should use stress testing exercises to take
corrective actions […] thus operating in the same way
as it does with ›economic‹ stress testing. «
Metrics for the long-term p. 32 Shifting profitability p. 34
Sustainable investments and innovation p. 35
Non-nancial disclosure,
reporting and accountability p. 35
Sustainable business
models p. 35
Sustainable consumption alternatives p. 37
Bank loans remain one of the main direct sources for both sustainable and unsustain-
able capital expenditure. In contrast to interventions in the capital markets, where
the shifting of existing assets between investors affects companies only indirectly,
bank loans provide direct funding for companies’ business activities. By extension, it
matters greatly to whom this money is lent and how it is spent.
When deciding to whom loans are awarded, banks take a variety of risks into consid-
eration. Supervisors inside the Network for Greening the Financial System (NGFS),
including the Bank of England’s Prudential Regulation Authority (PRA), are currently
exploring the environment-related risks through tools like scenario analysis, without
imposing any corrective actions such as additional capital requirements.
This policy aims to ensure that nancial supervisors like the PRA strengthen the
assessment of environment-related risks. As the materialisation of risks in part
depends on the implementation of other policy options like resource caps, such risk
assessments should not be considered in isolation. Most importantly, rather than
waiting for the data to rightly calibrate risks, regulators should follow the precaution-
ary principle when assessing these risks. In this spirit, they should:
Mandatory Financial Risk
Assessments and Disclosure
4.
65
Mandatory Financial Risk Assessments and DisclosureBuilding a resilient economy
Content
1. Make sure that banks do not neglect climate and nature-related risks.
2. Review banks’ risk assessment and risk management.
3. Use stress testing to take corrective actions and impose additional capital
buffers, whenever supervised nancial institutions fail to sufciently integrate
environment-related risks thus operating in the same way as it does with
economic” stress testing.
4. Force banks to integrate non-traditional risks by requiring them to hold higher
add-on capital that reflects such increased risks, under the discretionary
framework of Pillar II of the Basel Accord.
244
A possibility for intervention within the UK system is given within the framework
of the PRA capital buffer that is applied to supervised entities within the Pillar II B
guidelines of the Basel Accord. This buffer should be maintained by rms in addition
to their Pillar I (established risks categories) and Pillar II A (standardised risks
not captured in Pillar I) minimum capital requirements. The scoring of nancial
institutions in stress tests provides information about the size of the buffer.
The PRA is currently developing biennial climate scenarios that will start in 2021
and measure rms’ exposure to climate-related risks. Similar approaches can
be used for biodiversity related risks. To move beyond information gathering to
effectively regulating behaviour, the PRA should use the stress testing exercise to
take corrective actions and impose additional capital buffers where necessary, thus
operating in the same way as it does with “economic” stress testing.
Another input into calculating the capital buffer are supervisory judgements that, inter
alia, incorporate the sustainability of the business model of a nancial institution.
Accordingly, rms that are dependent on or specialised in lending to businesses with
high negative environmental impacts and do not have a credible transition plan could
be required to hold additional capital. Likewise, nancial rms that specialise in
nancing the transition could be rewarded with comparatively lower requirements.
In doing so, supervisors would incentivise banks to divest from unsustainable
activities, as the raising and holding of regulatory capital represents an additional
cost with no economic benet for them.
Where such actions are insufcient to address the risks of a nancial institution,
the PRA should also consider more interventionist approaches that supervisors have
applied within the Basel Framework of banking regulation. These include imposing limits
on lending, restrictions on dividends, capital distributions and bonuses, prohibitions on
investing in certain instruments, reduction of exposures to certain assets or positio
ns
(through hedging or sale of assets), and requiring the divestment of nancial products, e. g.
where the valuations of those products would not be deemed sufciently conservative.
245
66
Mandatory Financial Risk Assessments and DisclosureBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Finally, while the communication between banks and supervisors about risk
assessment frameworks is normally not communicated to the public, the Pillar III
mechanism that imposes market discipline through the disclosure of risks should be
used as an additional policy tool. While the PRA has already communicated to the
entities that are under its supervision that they should expect mandatory disclosure
in line with the Task Force on Climate-related Financial Disclosures (TCFD) framework
in the near future, a similar supervisory statement should be made about nature-
related risks.
246
Inspirations
NGFS members have started to assess the risk proles of “green” and “brown” assets.
Several regulators have started to “educate” banks by coming up with climate
stress tests and scenario analysis. A rst test of differential capital requirements
under Pillar II is carried out by the Hungarian Central Bank, which will be testing
preferential capital requirements for loans linked to energy efcient real estate
between 2020 and 2023.
Enablers and barriers
Enablers:
Work on taxonomies in several jurisdictions (EU, China, Bangladesh).
Work on scenario analysis enables forward looking assessments that project the
environmental risks into the future.
Awareness of the two-way relationship of nancial institutions being affected by
environmental risks and contributing to (future) environmental risks by nancing
harmful practices, a concept (double materiality) which is used in the EU’s non-
nancial reporting directive guidelines.
Barriers:
Pressures that nancial rms experience due to the COVID-19 pandemic.
67
Mandatory Financial Risk Assessments and DisclosureBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Windows of opportunity
Signicant regulatory momentum behind “sustainable nance. ESG-related funds
have outperformed the market indices during the pandemic.
The regulatory environment is sufciently institutionalised to not be derailed by
the crisis. In the EU, the Sustainable Finance Action Plan has received renewed
impetus.
The economic losses from COVID-19 show that environmental risks are massive
and real; This could add further momentum.
COP 26 adds momentum to biodiversity risks, especially in the UK.
Relevant stakeholders
Network for Greening the Financial System (NGFS), INSPIRE Research Collective,
ClimateWorks Foundation and Task force on Nature-Related Financial Disclosures
work streams on biodiversity are ongoing.
NGOs and research institutes like Finance Watch, Carbon Tracker, Third
Generation Environmentalism (E3G), the Institute for Climate Economics
(I4CE), 2 ° Investing Initiative and ShareAction have conducted research and /
or campaigned on differential capital requirements and risk assessment
methodologies for supervisors.
Associated clusters
68
Green Credit GuidanceBuilding a resilient economy
Content
» Central banks can influence the costs of green
capital through their own asset purchases and
collateral frameworks. «
Mandates and legal interpretations p. 31 Shifting profitability p. 34
Sustainable investments and innovation p. 35
Non-nancial disclosure,
reporting and accountability p. 35
Sustainable business
models p. 35
Sustainable consumption alternatives p. 37
Interventions by Central Banks (European Central Bank in the Eurozone, national
central banks outside) influence the costs of capital, which in turn have the effect of
guiding how capital is allocated by private banks. One of the most influential ways
in which central banks do this is by lending at low cost to banks via the Targeted
Long-Term Renancing Operations (TLTRO) programme in the Eurozone and the Term
Funding Scheme (TFS) in the UK, both of which are forms of Quantitative Easing. But
central banks also influence the costs of capital through their own asset purchases
and collateral frameworks and via their macroprudential policies which require
private banks to hold more capital against loans to some types of assets and less
against loans to others.
All of these activities can be considered as forms of “credit guidance” and can
be greened by building climate or other ecological risk metrics into how measures
are assessed or setting objectives related to climate risk.
247
Much of this can almost
certainly be achieved within the current mandates of most central banks. For instance,
if providing cheap liquidity under TLTRO or TFS, central banks could require private
banks to exclude certain loans, such as those to fossil fuel rms, on the basis that these
may pose a higher nancial risk over the loan period due to the climate risk they pose.
Alongside other measures to green the allocation of capital in the economy – most
notably the very strong pull of Public investment, the greening of Fiscal
frameworks and Mandatory risk assessments and disclosure already covered
in this report – green credit guidance by central banks could have a very signicant
impact on the selection of activities to receive loans. For instance, rms included in
the ECB’s collateral frameworks benetted from interest rates that were on average
Green Credit Guidance5.
69
Green Credit GuidanceBuilding a resilient economy
Content
one-third cheaper than those not included and that newly eligible rms received
more credit than ineligible ones. In other words, markets favour the assurance of
central bank support and allocate capital accordingly. Thus greening these measures
could have a very powerful effect on incentives and disincentives for high and low
carbon activities in the real economy.
Inspirations
Role of credit guidance in most Western countries post-war reconstruction and
growth processes and were central to Europe’s Golden Age.
Policies influencing the level of credit were imperative to the rapid expansion in
post-war Japan, the recent growth of China, the development of East Asian mir-
acles, and the growth of “other” emerging economies.
248
It is only in liberal, post
1980 western economies that the guidance of credit by central banks has given
way to the mantra of market neutrality.
249
Enablers and barriers
Enablers:
Reducing risks in the balance sheets of banks. A recently published research
by the New Economics Foundation has shown that current Bank of England QE
programmes are not only carbon intensive, but, more so than the UK economy
itself, introducing signicant climate-nancial risk onto the bank’s balance sheet
and pumping cheap money into fossil fuels.
250
The ECB’s mandate includes a requirement for the bank in effect to support the
European Commission’s policy agenda
251
, it would arguably not only be odd but
also opposing its mandate if the ECB did not guide credit along the lines of the
European Green Deal.
Commitment of the UK government to its 2050 targets and requirements of the
Paris Agreement could be used as the guiding star for central bank activities and
could potentially be utilized to hold them accountable if current carbon-intensive
renancing and asset purchases continue.
Past guidelines of monetary policy, are reaching their limits. High public debt has
not led to rising interest rates; inflation is less of a problem than the persistent
lack of demand.
252
70
Green Credit GuidanceBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Barriers:
Green credit guidance may be seen as active and therefore non-market-neutral by
conservative central bankers and therefore offending the tenets of independence
from government.
Windows of opportunity
The post pandemic crisis and the need for cash and credit to be pumped into the
economy by central banks creates the policy frameworks in which green forms of
credit guidance could help reduce future risks.
The pre-pandemic commitment by both the ECB and BoE to review monetary
policy frameworks along with the increasing traction of Paris Commitments create
the processes by which experts, economists and campaigners can gather support
and evidence for the need of establishing green credit guidance as the new norm.
Relevant stakeholder clusters
The Network for Greening the Finance System (NGFS) is a key insider forum for
developing credible, evidence-based frameworks.
253
The ClimateWorks Foundation has created a stream of research called INSPIRE, in
parallel with the NGFS, to help unblock analytical concerns and ll evidence gaps.
Growing cliusters of policy-focussed groups (Council on Economic Policies in
Switzerland, The Institute for Innovation and Public Purpose at UCL in London, the
New Economics Foundation and Positive Money, both in the UK and EU), which
collaborate to support the development of credible policy to support green central
banking and to work on the inside to champion progressive banks and individuals.
350.org, Greenpeace and Frances Reclaim Finance are also shaping to develop
more outsider campaigns.
Associated clusters
71
Land Value TaxBuilding a resilient economy
Content
» The uplift in land value, which often affords owners of
land considerable income, remains largely untaxed. «
Limiting power and empowerment for change p. 27 Shifting profitabil-
ity p. 34
Sustainable investments and innovation p. 35
Sustainable
consumption alternatives p. 37
Affordability and fairness p. 39
In transformation, it is important to primarily include those people who are most
affected by the transition: Because they will potentially lose their jobs, have to
develop new skills or will see their whole region undergo tremendous change. One
possibility is nancial support. Of all the possibilities mentioned in the chapter on
Citizens, we focus on the Land Value Tax, because it is one way to fundamentally
change the distribution of income and thus also of prosperity.
A land value tax increases in the value of land, which accrued in value because
of community and not individual effort.
254
It can either be implemented as part of a
wider tax system or as the predominant tax in a new system that seeks to price the
use of natural assets whose supply has hard boundaries. Land and property are taxed,
for instance in the case of Stamp Duty when a property on a piece of land is sold or
through Inheritance Tax or when inherited. However, the uplift in value, which often
affords owners of land considerable income through charging rents or sale at a
higher price level, remains largely untaxed.
Proponents of Land Value Tax (LVT) have long argued that it can:
1. Help correct wealth inequalities by taxing windfall increases in land value and
thereby decrease power imbalances.
2. Deter speculative acquisition of land and “land banking” and shift investment
from land to productive assets in the real economy.
3. Help economic development in areas where land values are low, versus those
where values are high.
Land Value Tax6.
72
Land Value TaxBuilding a resilient economy
Content
4. Increase the efciency of land use in rural areas and reduce soil sealing and the
fragmentation of landscape for example by investing into buildings, which facili-
tate the provision of affordable housing without designating new building land.
5. Boost government tax receipts, which could assist with tackling major challenges,
such as ecological crises.
The Mirrlees Review of the UK Tax System, published in 2011, concluded that a land
value tax would address many of the inequities and structural issues, arguing that,
“In particular, there is a strong case for levying a land value tax, which is a tax on pure
rent – if the practical difculty of valuing land separately from the buildings on it can
be overcome.
255
The UK is one of the most unequal OECD countries and its taxation reflects this, the
principal symptom being the disparity between taxes on income, which operate at
a higher effective rate than taxes on wealth.
256
Steeply rising land values in the UK
are one of the main components of wealth acquisition. This effect has been very
unevenly spread with land values in some locations rising at much higher rates than
in others. Land in the UK is worth an estimated £ 4.057 trillion, which is more than
two-fths of the nation’s net worth.
257
Total UK land value has increased by more
than 450 % since 1995, a rise that signicantly outstrips that of the assets on the
land.
258
These increases in land value are a windfall for those who have benetted,
especially because of the location of the land they own.
Because land is not frequently valued, there are few estimates of the revenue that
could be raised from taxing land values. One study, which focuses on London, found
that, based on 2015 valuations, an LVT of 1.97 % could raise around £ 6.5 billion in
2017.
259
An ongoing study has suggested a locally-levied tax on commercial landown-
ers at a rate of 2.9 % of capital values could raise up to £ 6 billion.
260
Different options
for a LVT have been discussed.
261, 262
These include the extension of existing land and
property taxes, the use of a land value tax to replace all existing taxes on land and
property or the use of a Local Land Value Tax to replace business rates and council tax.
Inspirations
The 2018 Land Value Tax review, conducted for the Scottish Land Commission,
sampled 61 countries with some form of land value tax and found that most
implement such a tax alongside existing land and property taxation measures.
263
In particular the study highlights ve case studies – Queensland (Australia), Estonia,
New Zealand, Denmark and South Africa.
73
Land Value TaxBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Enablers and barriers
Enablers:
LVTs are a tool for wealth redistribution and for the recognition of land as a
valuable asset.
Potential to increase tax revenues and nance recovery programs and the
green transition with few impacts on economic recovery.
264
Barriers:
High administrative costs of implementation, given that taxing land requires it to
be parcelled and valued, its interaction with other land and property taxes and the
need to revise the planning system to work alongside a Land Value Tax.
265
Political viability. In the UK, the relatively undisturbed centuries-old pattern of
land ownership, the huge rise in land values over the past two decades and
the predilection of UK policy towards home ownership, locks together an old and
new constituency that would likely oppose a Land Value Tax and would wield
considerable power and influence over government.
266
Windows of opportunity
Renancing the COVID-19 economic recovery programmes will require new sources
of income for the State in the medium-term. A tax levied on land values and hence on
landlords, could tap into a seam of wealth that has hitherto remain untaxed. At the
same time, it has negligible negative effects on economic recovery compared to other
types of taxes. Revenues can help local authorities or high-street businesses in the
post COVID-19 period deal with even greater nancial pressures. Further, the income
generated can support low-income households in the green transformation. This can
create acceptance for the measures proposed in the other chapters.
Associated clusters
74
Resource Caps and BiodiversityBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Resource Caps and Biodiversity
» A tax or license trading system for resource use (similar to
that for carbon) based on biodiversity impacts of the taxed
resource could address biodiversity loss. «
Fiscal policy and growth independence p. 26 Limiting power and
empowerment for change p. 27
Shifting profitability p. 34
Sustainable investments and innovation p. 35
Non-nancial
disclosure, reporting and accountability p. 35
Sustainable consumption
alternatives p. 37
Sufciency p. 38
Currently, all drivers of biodiversity loss are accelerating, while the decline of global biodi-
versity is unprecedented.
267
The overuse of resources has been identied as the main
driver of biodiversity loss by researchers: 90 % of biodiversity damage and water stress
are caused by resource extraction and processing.
268
So far, strategies such as implement-
ing a circular economy have not proven to be sufcient in halting biodiversity loss.
269
Thus, there is an emerging consensus among scientists that global resource
extraction of renewable and non-renewable materials needs a cap, estimated
roughly at a yearly maximum of 50 billion tons globally.
270, 271, 272, 273
While this aggre-
gate level lacks a break down on resources and their associated impacts, studies
have shown that avoidance costs for stopping biodiversity loss by reducing material
consumption are lower than overall expected damage and repair costs.
274
The
introduction of a tax or license trading system for resource use (similar to that for
carbon) based on biodiversity impacts of the taxed resource could address these
challenges effectively:
1. Resource caps establish limits on resource throughput and ultimately constrain
consumption and production.
275, 276, 277
2. Caps support transformative change as increasing costs for resource inputs
modify the competitiveness dynamics in a market economy, consequently
requiring companies to redesign products and business models by taking resource
limitations into account.
7.
75
Resource Caps and BiodiversityBuilding a resilient economy
Content
3. Resource caps force both private and public investments to take biodiversity
impact implicitly into account (see → Modernising UK scal rules and New
national investment authority) and ultimately, channel investment towards a
circular economy.
To implement resource caps the following steps are needed:
1. Agreeing on a science-based global goal on biodiversity loss (similar to 1.5 °C
goal in Paris Agreement) and derive resource budgets and reduction needs.
278
2. Dening assessment approaches to estimate biodiversity impacts by a given
resource in a preventive manner that allows for data gaps (similar to CO
2
equivalents).
3. Implementation of a resource tax resource, increasing over time, until the
resource reduction target is reached or implementation of a cap and trade scheme
that issues resource licences. Taxes or licences would differentiate between
biodiversity impacts of resources.
Our survey results suggest that resource caps could provide a crucial new source
of scal revenue which “enables the UK to [tackle pressing challenges] such as
zero-carbon innovation / infrastructure and regeneration of food, farming and land
use”. At the same time, resource caps could also send “important signals about
incentives and societal priorities”, both domestically and internationally.
Inspirations
If applied in the right manner that addresses the downsides
279
of existing approaches
like the EU Emissions Trading System (EU ETS)
280, 281
cap and trade schemes, they can
be a cost-effective option to limit resource use. Other options like resource taxes can
be just as cost-effective. The ITQ system and resource rent tax in Icelandic sheries
provided the correct incentives for sustainable harvesting of sh and made it possible
for shers to safeguard stocks through decreasing effort and catches, while at the same
time securing their long-term economic future.
282
Other examples include the Alaska
Permanent Fund
283
, Earth Atmospheric Trust
284
and the Norwegian Nature Index.
285, 286
Cap and trade schemes make use of market efciency, which will ultimately allo-
cate the resource rights at their highest valued uses.
287
In addition, raising awareness
on contributions of biodiversity and ecosystem services to human wellbeing can be
promoted.
288
Finally, caps on resource use should go hand in hand with measures to
redistribute rents and channel the gained money back into society, for instance by
funding green projects.
289
This is why our set of policies also includes land value taxes,
green credit guidance and a Wellbeing Budget.
76
Resource Caps and BiodiversityBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Enablers and barriers
Enablers:
The Science Based Targets Initiative endeavours to develop science-based targets
also for biodiversity loss.
290,
291
Cap and trade schemes make use of market efciency which will ultimately
allocate the resource rights at their highest valued uses.
292
Raising awareness of contributions of biodiversity and ecosystem services
to human wellbeing.
293
Caps on resource use should go hand in hand with measures to redistribute rents
and rentier to channel the gained money back into society, for instance by funding
green projects.
294
This is why our set of policies also includes land value taxes,
green credit guidance and a Wellbeing Budget.
Barriers:
In contrast to GHG emissions, biodiversity impact of resources and products is
difcult to assess as a broad range of variables influence the biodiversity impact
of materials. Thus, a measurement system capturing the biodiversity impact of
resources has to be developed (see EBTs).
A lack of consideration of territorial differences in biodiversity could be
problematic when implementing resource caps.
295
Explicit disclosure of trade-offs and synergies between different objectives have
to be taken into account and a more balanced and transparent funding between
production of agricultural commodities and delivery of public goods is necessary.
296
Socioeconomic factors should be considered, to avoid welfare losses through
regressive policies, for instance, by weakening the position of domestic industries
or bounding income from low income groups through signicant price increases
for essential goods.
297
77
Resource Caps and BiodiversityBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Windows of opportunity
The ongoing conversation in Whitehall on substituting the EU ETS with a domestic
carbon trading mechanism offers an opportunity to ensure that robust and
effective caps are introduced to limit the impact of carbon intensive sectors.
Even within agriculture and transport sectors, current leading proposals on
decarbonisation have variations of resource caps with elements of trading for
credits (either in the form of electric vehicles or peatland carbon).
Current legislation going through parliament on agriculture, environment, sheries
and trade all offer challenging but key parliamentary opportunities to introduce
resource caps, where relevant.
Relevant stakeholder
Given the complexity and nascent nature of this policy idea, it is not easily
communicated in campaigning. But given the existing windows of opportunity,
the following clusters are well-placed to take this issue forward in terms of
policy development and advocacy.
1. The Greener UK coalition in the UK working on post-Brexit implications
for the environment and natural resources.
2. The Build Back Better coalition of progressive NGOs and grassroots
groups working towards a green recovery.
Associated clusters
8.
78
Environmental Border TaxBuilding a resilient economy
Content
» Establishing EBTs would treat domestic and offshore
resource extraction and use equally, based on their
respective biodiversity impact. «
Shifting profitability p. 34
Sustainable investments and
innovation p. 35 Non-nancial disclosure, reporting and accountability p. 35
Sustainable business models p. 35 Sustainable consumption
alternatives p. 37
Sufciency p. 38
To halt the unprecedented decline of global biodiversity and to ensure the effec-
tiveness of unilateral policy efforts such as resource caps, biodiversity offsetting or
environmental border taxes (EBTs) can present a crucial complementary measure
to prevent biodiversity leakage and to safeguard domestic competitiveness.
298
In the case of climate change, there is a growing consensus that border taxes such as
border carbon taxes (BCTs) will constitute an essential component of the response
to climate change.
299
This is because BCTs can help level uneven carbon taxation
schemes and are the only unilateral policy option that offers both effective protec-
tion against leakage of production and an incentive for other countries to strengthen
their climate efforts.
300
In our survey, the combination of resource caps and EBTs has
been described as “[potentially] having a big impact at home and [an even stronger]
impact abroad as it is […] a more fundamental break from the current paradigm.
We propose to widen the idea of BCTs for avoiding leakage from carbon taxation
to a wider EBT that aims to avoid leakage from resource taxation, as proposed in the
previous chapter. Biodiversity leakage describes the phenomenon of biodiversity
damaging activities relocating elsewhere after being stopped locally, for example by a
cap on resource extraction that is harmful to biodiversity.
301
Leakage can lead to high
net biodiversity loss since it is difcult to measure or prevent.
302, 303
Establishing EBTs would treat domestic and offshore resource extraction and
use equally, based on their respective biodiversity impact. Environmental Border
Taxes (EBTs) would be charged depending on biodiversity impacts associated with
certain resources. This can level the competitive playing eld, reduce leakage, and
Environmental Border Tax
79
Environmental Border TaxBuilding a resilient economy
Content
incentivise trade partners to strengthen biodiversity policy efforts.
304
Thus, preserving
competitiveness of domestic industries, if faced with domestic taxation schemes
(see → Resource caps) and addressing the problem of uneven resource reduction
efforts by including imports in or exempting exports from biodiversity constraints.
In particular, tariffs on products containing resources with strong biodiversity
impacts, such as agriculture, rare earths and chemicals, would presumably reduce the
leakage of production facilities that use these resources. When compared to unilateral
measures such as resource caps alone, EBTs may be most effective in leakage reduc-
tion and promotion of global cost-effectiveness as is the case for carbon taxes.
305
To avoid the risks of trade wars driven by unilateral protectionist trade-policy, an
EBT should not be established single-handedly. We propose to complement it with
the establishment of an international UK biodiversity fund. Revenues from tariffs
would partly be used to equip the fund. Offshore trading-partners could apply for
funding with projects that aim to reduce the biodiversity impact from the resources
used in their business model.
We identied the following steps that would be necessary to design EBTs
successfully:
1. Agreeing on a science-based global goal on biodiversity loss (equivalent
to 1.5 °C goal in Paris Agreement).
306
2. Dening assessment approaches to estimate biodiversity impacts through
resource use in a preventive manner that allows for data gaps (similar to CO
2
equivalents).
3. Designing a standard to calculate product-based biodiversity impacts by
trading partners.
4. Implementing a UK biodiversity fund to support offshore industries with
reducing their biodiversity impact.
5. Imposing adjusted tariffs for imported goods, where rms cannot prove that
the biodiversity impact from the resources contained in the product is below a
certain threshold.
Inspirations
The UK would be a forerunner by implementing a broader environmental border tax
(EBT), rather than limited border carbon taxes. In fact, this will be the rst of its kind,
however, the EU is currently leading the change in this policy sphere.
80
Environmental Border TaxBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Enablers and barriers
Enablers:
For BCAs, there is a consensus that these can be a WTO-consistent policy
tool when designed and implemented properly.
307
Increasing awareness for the necessity to decelerate biodiversity loss.
Barriers:
Difculty to draw a strict line between sectors covered and not covered.
308
Considerable variation across sectors in resource intensity and associated
biodiversity impacts.
Complexity in calculating the appropriate EBT margin, high administrative costs
and a requirement for a strong welfare justication, as for carbon.
309
Risk ofcascading protectionism” with tariffs being possibly extended to
industries further along global value chains.
310
Potential misuse of border measures for strategic reasons in presence of
market power on international markets.
311
Possible violation to the WTO’s most-favoured-nation treatment (GATT) and may
conflict with the principle of common but differentiated responsibilities (CBDR).
312
Windows of opportunity
The major window of opportunity is the EU and the Commission indicating a strong
interest in pursuing an environmental border tax, which is bound to draw in the UK
as a close trading partner.
The post COVID-19 economic recovery requires a wide set of tax levers for the
Treasury to utilise in order to raise revenue and bridge the huge scal decit. If
pitched properly, border adjustment taxes could prove to be a vital tool in the tax
toolbox.
Our survey suggests that the UK is well positioned to work on EBTs in the post-
Brexit period. Brexit will result in a more independent decision-making process
that can build up on the heritage of EU environmental standards and carbon
pricing / trading at the same time.
81
Environmental Border TaxBuilding a resilient economy
Content
Relevant stakeholders
Influential think tanks like Policy Exchange and Aurora energy have previously
made the case for carbon border adjustments tax alongside other rightwing
groups.
The UK government’s chief climate advisory body, the Committee on Climate
Change, has advocated for a carbon border adjustments tax to achieve net
zero. This offers a clear baseline to build on extending the tax to wider biodiversity
issues, beyond just carbon.
Other potential supporters include both economic and environmental advocacy
institutions and NGOs.
82
Interim conclusionBuilding a resilient economy
Content
The interplay between the policies
presented here is as important as the
details of individual policies.
The policies presented here are mutually support-
ive. Most policies address several of the interven-
tion areas listed in Table 1. A wellbeing budget for
the UK, the national investment authority, manda-
tory nancial risk assessments and a green credit
guidance all aim to increase and strengthen invest-
ment in the green economy. A modernised set of
government’s scal rules, a land value tax, and
resource caps create the necessary scal leeway.
Resource caps ensure that these policies are effec-
tive in reducing resource use through absolute lim-
its and a dynamic steering effect via prices. Last-
ly, a land value tax can ensure social acceptance,
while environmental border taxes aim to support
domestic economic actors.
The interaction between the policies is illustrated
in the graphic on page 84. Arrows indicate the flow
of nancial resources for example investments
or payments that flow into unsustainable sectors
with low wellbeing gains, or into sustainable sec-
tors with high wellbeing gains.
Originating from the state, shifting from the
current national budget to a Wellbeing Budget
would force policymakers to implement proce-
dures (indicator sets, models, decision-process)
to ensure that public spending generates posi-
tive impacts for wellbeing and the environment.
It would thereby ensure that the state invests in
the sectors that are important for the society such
as resilience, economic security, care, education,
infrastructures. However, this would require that
a sufcient amount of public spending is availa-
ble to do so. This would be achieved by reassess-
ing scal space. A new scal framework supports
the Wellbeing Budget. By including long-term con-
siderations into the associated national assess-
ment framework, more space will be available for
investments to enhance resilience, mitigate cli-
mate change and conserve biodiversity.
In order to effectively utilise that scal space
to deliver the objectives as outlined in the Well-
being Budget, a New Investment Authority would
be responsible for ensuring that investments are
channelled into the appropriate sectors. It would
also provide credits and support for both business-
es with a sustainable business model and consum-
ers who want to purchase sustainable products.
These investment policy measures would consti-
tute a tremendous shift, by restraining the power
of unsustainable businesses.
These public investments would impact cap-
ital flows from public banks and the central bank
and crowd-in private nance. In addition, two pol-
icies can make private banks shift their invest-
ments towards more sustainable sectors and busi-
ness models on their own and make environmen-
Interim conclusion
The interplay of policy proposals
83
Interim conclusionBuilding a resilient economy
Content
tally harmful activities more expensive. The rst is
a mandatory risk assessment and disclosure of cli-
mate and biodiversity related risks of credit pro-
vided by private banks, which makes environmen-
tal risks more transparent. These risk assessments
would support the second policy, green credit guid-
ance, which would drive investment in sustainable
business and raise economic and environmental
resilience by lowering environmental pressures.
These policies would reduce costs for sustain-
able business models and create economies of
scale, thus boosting green innovation in the mass
market. Sustainable products would become more
affordable and unsustainable products less so.
However, there might still be some price increas-
es, so to counter this we need some carefully tar-
geted redistributive policies to ensure a just transi-
tion and build overall political and public support for
the package of measures. This would ensure that
all people have access to basic goods and services
such as housing, water, mobility, energy and food.
To raise revenue for these efforts in a way that
would also coherently support the goals of efcient
use of natural resources, a land value tax could be
introduced.
It is impossible to foresee whether a different
incentive structure and nancial environment will
indeed prevent the costs of the environmental cri-
sis. The above measures may generate relative
gains, like increase material and energy efcien-
cy and carbon intensity. Resource caps can make
sure that these gains translate into an absolute
reduction of resource use and thereby ensure that
the economy operates within planetary boundaries.
While other policies serve to redirect investment,
resource caps go further, directly addressing the
protability of certain business models. Resource
caps would restrict activities that harm biodiver-
sity by charging higher prices for resource licenc-
es or imposing taxes. Due to this policys impact
on competitiveness and protability, Environmen-
tal Border Taxes would be a crucial complementa-
ry measure in protecting biodiversity leakage and
safeguarding domestic competitiveness.
It is important to note that to effectively restruc-
ture the economic and nancial system towards
sustainability, it is necessary to apply policy pack-
ages, rather than individual policies. However,
many of the prioritised policies in the package-
may be replaced with others that deliver a simi-
lar effect; it is only necessary that the impacts of
the chosen policies are addressed simultaneously.
For example, the goal of a land value tax or inher-
itance taxes is to lessen the extent of power imbal-
ances by reducing wealth accumulation from land
ownership. These taxes could supply households
with income needed to purchase basic goods and
services, whose prices might have risen due to the
impacts of other policies, such as resource caps.
Private Banks
Central Bank
New Framework for
Assessing Fiscal Space
Trading Partners
Environmental Border Taxes
8.
New Investment Facility
Wellbeing Budget
Credit Guidance
3.
2.
Mandatory Risk
Assessments and Disclosure
4.
1.
5.
Ressource Caps7.
Investment Facility
Government
high-income
households
low-income
households
Land Value Tax
6.
Planetary Boundaries
Arrows indicate the flow of nancial resources into the resilient
(
) or the extractive economy (
).
⬑ These boxes are policies to change the flows.
Legend
Extractive
Economy
Resilient
Economy
Wellbeing Budget
1.
86
In place of a conclusion: A story of hopeBuilding a resilient economy
Content
This report and the research underpinning it is
an attempt to better understand what system-
ic change towards a more resilient and sustaina-
ble economy might look like for the UK. We have
outlined eight key proposals that provide an effec-
tive route to transforming the economy and shap-
ing markets and the behaviour of a variety of actors
in the process.
Despite the many potential benets of the pro-
posals presented in this report, they lack wide-
spread awareness or support. The world is quite
a long way from being able to implement some of
them. One reason is that the destination of a differ-
ent economy can feel abstract or irrelevant, espe-
cially to audiences that are not immersed in com-
plex economic theory or policymaking. As a result,
there is a dearth of positive visions of the future
in the media. This is a problem, as humans make
sense of the world through stories – and these
stories shape how we behave in it.
Narratives in public discourse shift culture
and produce tangible impact through policy
change, behaviour change and advocacy. With this
in mind, we urgently need to move past the focus
on discussing what is wrong with the current sys-
tem, towards sharing positive, new narratives that
inspire people to imagine a resilient economy that
promotes human and ecological wellbeing, and to
start engaging with on how to actually make this
happen. With imagination comes hope, and with
hope, action. Clear narratives around resilience
and wellbeing, which succinctly summarise the
societal vision towards which policies work, are
crucial to provide direction, motivation and wide-
spread support. This requires seeing an idea put
into practice and thus getting a sense of what it
looks and feels like.
What might this resilient economy
look like?
For policymakers, it might entail more collabora-
tion with all stakeholders, including more partic-
ipatory processes with citizens and new partner-
ships to co-create and implement transformative
policy projects. Policymakers would incentivise
agencies and non-governmental actors to demon-
strate their positive impact on a suite of collective
wellbeing indicators in order to receive resourc-
es. They would be seen as the ones navigating the
economy into the future, as the supporters and the
enablers of the transformation.
For investors, the policies mentioned in this report
would reframe the goal of nancial markets from
maximising short-term nancial performance, to
the allocation of capital to support sustainable
outcomes. In order to make investments with this
goal in mind, investors would be empowered with
In place of a conclusion:
A story of hope
» Its not enough to imagine another world is
possible, we need to feel and taste it. «
— Naomi Klein
87
In place of a conclusion: A story of hopeBuilding a resilient economy
Content
the right information via strict standardised mon-
itoring mechanisms that allow for the assessment
and comparison of sustainability metrics of differ-
ent business models, along with traditional nan-
cial metrics, and would be incentivised by new reg-
ulatory and market based frameworks. New invest-
ment opportunities created by governments would
create more options for investors looking to invest
in more socially responsible ways. Finally, biodi-
versity labels, environmental externalities assess-
ments, and a common international standard for
calculating carbon emissions embodied in goods,
would provide the information needed to identify
sustainable nancial products. This would lead to
adequate investment in innovative and sustainable
businesses.
For business leaders, the proposed policies would
reframe the denition of success: to consider the
wider impacts on environment & society, not just
short-term shareholder prot. Based on this new
modus operandi, businesses would make deci-
sions that favour people and the planet, along with
generating prot. Sustainable operations would
likely be more protable due to lower taxation, an
increasing demand for sustainable products from
citizens, improved reputation, reduced risk and
increased innovation due to increased nancial
incentives from investors and government.
For citizens, proposed policies would result in
being treated like people, rather than as consum-
ers. All people would have nancial stability, due to
the eradication of the underlying drivers of nan-
cial inequality and concentration of power. Respon-
sible citizens would be sustainable consumers who
collectively respect environmental boundaries and
promote social justice and equal opportunities.
Satisfaction of their needs would not always rely on
more cars, Iphones and other goods, but could also
be obtained through immaterial services, strong
social relationships and meaningful activities.
It is the interplay between these actors that forms
the basis of a resilient economy. Therefore, it is
crucial to involve a relevant number of different
stakeholders: it is vital to reach a critical mass of
people and organisations coming together to form
a movement to create systemic change and call on
policymakers to implement the necessary reforms.
No one alone can achieve it. But together, actors
can demand that policy creates the framework
that makes sustainable behaviour easier and paves
the way to a resilient economy. We are aware that
the proposals in this report are far-reaching. Their
implementation is seemingly difcult. But we are
convinced that they are necessary. We need the
courage to dare something new. With this report,
we invite you to dare, so that the prosperity of
today will benet our children tomorrow and we
can ensure survival on this planet.
Content
Endnotes
1 Widmaier, W. (2016). Economic Ideas in Political Time:
The Rise and Fall of Economic Orders from the Progressive
Era to the Global Financial Crisis. Cambridge, United
Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.
2 Battersby, B., Raphael W., & Ture E. (2020). Tracking
the $9 Trillion Global Fiscal Support to Fight COVID-19. IMF
Blog. Retrieved from https://blogs.imf.org/2020/05/20/
tracking-the-9-trillion-global-scal-support-to-ght-
COVID-19
3 Anderson J., Bergamini E., Brekelmans S., Cameron
A., Darvas Z., Domínguez Jíménez, M., & Midões C. (2020).
The scal response to the economic fallout from 
the coronavirus. Bruegel Datasets. Retrieved from
https://www.bruegel.org/publications/datasets/covid-
national-dataset/#uk
4 Our World in Data (2020). Total Conrmed COVID-19 
Cases per Million People. Retrieved from https://ourworldin-
data.org/grapher/total-conrmed-cases-of-COVID-19-per-
million-people (24.09.2020)
5 Goodman, P. (2020, August 11). Sweden Has Become
the World’s Cautionary Tale. The New York Times. Retrieved
from https://www.nytimes.com/2020/07/07/business/
sweden-economy-coronavirus.html (24.09.2020)
6 Johnson, C. K. et al. (2020). Global Shifts in Mammalian
Population Trends Reveal Key Predictors of Virus Spillover
Risk. Proceedings of the Royal Society B, 287(1924)
Retrieved from https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2019.2736
7 Shukla, P. R. et al. (2018). Global Warming of 1.5°C. An
IPCC Special Report on the Impacts of Global Warming of
1.5°C above Pre-Industrial Levels and Related Global Green-
house Gas Emission Pathways, in the Context of Strength-
ening the Global Response to the Threat of Climate Change,
Sustainable Development, and Efforts to Eradicate Poverty.
IPCC. Retrieved from https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/
uploads/sites/2/2019/06/SR15_Full_Report_High_Res.pdf
8 Díaz, S. et al. (2019). The global assessment report
on biodiversity and ecosystem services. Summary for
Policymakers. IPBES. Retrieved from https://ipbes.net/
sites/default/les/inline/les/ipbes_global_assess-
ment_report_summary_for_policymakers.pdf
9 World Economic Forum. (2020). The Future of Nature
and Business. World Economic Forum New Nature Economy
Report II. Retrieved from http://www3.weforum.org/docs/
WEF_The_Future_Of_Nature_And_Business_2020.pdf
10 Dasgupta, P. (2020). The Dasgupta Review. Independ-
ent Review on the Economics of Biodiversity. UK Treasury
Interim Report. Retrieved from https://assets.publishing.
service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/
attachment_data/le/882222/The_Economics_of_Biodiver-
sity_The_Dasgupta_Review_Interim_Report.pdf
11 Glanemann, N., Willner, S., & Levermann, A. (2020).
Paris Climate Agreement Passes the Cost-Benet Test.
Nature Communications, 11. Retrieved from https://www.
nature.com/articles/s41467-019-13961-1
12 Stern, N. et al. (2006). Stern Review: The Economics of
Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
13 Díaz, S. et al. (2019). The global assessment report
on biodiversity and ecosystem services. Summary for
Policymakers. IPBES. Retrieved from https://ipbes.net/
sites/default/les/inline/les/ipbes_global_assess-
ment_report_summary_for_policymakers.pdf
14 FAO. (2016). Pollinators Vital to Our Food Supply under
Threat. Food and Agriculture Organisation of the United
Nations. Retrieved from http://www.fao.org/news/story/en/
item/384726/icode/ (24.09.2020)
15 Cf. Rounsevell, M. D. A. et al. (2020). A Biodiversity
Target Based on Species Extinctions. Science, 368 (6496),
1193–1195. Retrieved from https://science.sciencemag.
org/content/368/6496/1193?rss=1
16 Ceballos, G. et al. (2015). Accelerated Modern Human
– Induced Species Losses: Entering the Sixth Mass Extinction.
Science Advances, 1(5)
17 Dasgupta, P. (2020). The Dasgupta Review. Independ-
ent Review on the Economics of Biodiversity. UK Treasury
Interim Report. Retrieved from https://assets.publishing.
service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/
attachment_data/le/882222/The_Economics_of_Biodiver-
sity_The_Dasgupta_Review_Interim_Report.pdf
18 Mitchell, A. (2013). Risk and Resilience. From
Good Idea to Good Practice. OECD Development
Co-operation Working Papers. Retrieved from https://
www.oecd-ilibrary.org/docserver/5k3ttg4cxcbp-en.
pdf?expires=1600932101&id=id&accname=guest&check-
sum=2BECA6A3E9902F536FF82B27CBED017A
19 Cf. European Commission (2020). Charting the
Course towards a more resilient Europe. Retrieved from
https://ec.europa.eu/info/sites/info/les/strategic_fore-
sight_report_2020_1.pdf
20 Jackson, T. (2017). Prosperity without Growth: Founda-
tions for the Economy of Tomorrow (2nd ed.). London; New
York: Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group
21 Raworth, K. (2017). Doughnut Economics: Seven Ways
to Think like a 21st Century Economist. White River Junction,
Vermont: Chelsea Green Publishing
22 Mazzucato, M. (2018). The Value of Everything: Making
and Taking in the Global Economy. London, UK: Allan Lane
Penguin Books
88
Content
23 D’Alisa, G., Demaria F., & Kallis, G. (2015). Degrowth:
A Vocabulary for a New Era. Routledge, Taylor & Francis
Group.. Retrieved from http://public.eblib.com/choice/
publicfullrecord.aspx?p=1843450
24 OECD. (2011). Towards Green Growth.
OECDPublishing. Retrieved from http://dx.doi.
org/10.1787/9789264111318-en
25 UNEP. (2011). Towards a Green Economy: Pathways
to Sustainable Development and Poverty Eradication – A
Synthesis for Policy Makers. Retrieved from https://www.
unep.org/explore-topics/green-economy (24.09.2020)
26 Stiglitz, J. (2019). Fighting the Climate Crisis Need Not
Mean Halting Economic Growth. The Guardian. Retrieved
from https://www.theguardian.com/business/2019/
dec/09/climate-crisis-economic-growth-green-economy
(24.09.2020)
27 Krugman, P. (2010). Climate Change - Building a Green
Economy. The New York Times. Retrieved from https://www.
nytimes.com/2010/04/11/magazine/11Economy-t.html.
(24.09.2020)
28 Shukla, P. R. et al. (2018). Global Warming of 1.5°C.
An IPCC Special Report on the Impacts of Global Warming of
1.5°C above Pre-Industrial Levels and Related Global Green-
house Gas Emission Pathways, in the Context of Strength-
ening the Global Response to the Threat of Climate Change,
Sustainable Development, and Efforts to Eradicate Poverty.
IPCC. Retrieved from https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/
uploads/sites/2/2019/06/SR15_Full_Report_High_Res.pdf.
29 Díaz, S. et al. (2019). The global assessment report
on biodiversity and ecosystem services. Summary for
Policymakers. IPBES. Retrieved from https://ipbes.net/
sites/default/les/inline/les/ipbes_global_assess-
ment_report_summary_for_policymakers.pdf.
30 World Economic Forum. (2020). The Future of Nature
and Business. World Economic Forum New Nature Economy
Report II. Retrieved from http://www3.weforum.org/docs/
WEF_The_Future_Of_Nature_And_Business_2020.pdf.
31 North, D. (2005). Understanding the Process of
Economic Change. Princeton: Princeton University Press
32 Ibid
33 Lamb, W. et al. (2020). Discourses of Climate Delay.
Global Sustainability, 3(17). Retrieved from
https://doi.org/10.1017/sus.2020.13
34 Alberto, A. & Giuliano, P. (2015). Culture and Institu-
tions. Journal of Economic Literature, 53(4)
35 Kania, J., Kramer, M., & Senge, P. (2018). The Water
of Systems Change. FSG Report. Retrieved from
https://www.fsg.org/publications/water_of_systems_
change#download-area.
36 However, these clusters should be taken with a grain
of salt, as due to the limited scope of the report, these do
not represent a structured review on the global literature on
systemic change.
37 High-impact clusters are the clusters at the top of
Table 1
38 Governance can be dened as the formal and informal
(both public and private) rules, rule-making systems, and
actor-networks at all levels of human society (from local to
global) that are set up to steer societies towards positive
outcomes and away from harmful ones (adapted from Bier-
mann, F., & Boas, I. (2010). Preparing for a Warmer World:
Towards a Global Governance System to Protect Climate
Refugees. Global Environmental Politics, 10(1), 60–88
39 Seto, K. et al. (2016). Carbon Lock-In: Types, Causes,
and Policy Implications. Annual Review of Environment and
Resources 41(1), 425–52
40 United Nations. (2020). The Sustainable Development
Goals Report. UN Department of Economic and Social
Affairs. Retrieved from https://unstats.un.org/sdgs/
report/2020/
41 Watson, R. et al. (2019). The Truth Behind the Climate
Pledges. International Institute for Applied Systems Analy-
sis. Retrieved from http://pure.iiasa.ac.at/id/eprint/16143/
42 Climate Action Tracker (2020). United Kingdom.
Retrieved from https://climateactiontracker.org/countries/
uk/
43 European Union. (2020). Sustainable Development
in the European Union, Monitoring Report on Progress
towards the SDGS in an EU Context (4th ed.). Luxembourg:
Publications Ofce of the European Union
44 Yeo, S. (2019). Climate, Nature and Our 1.5°C Future
– A Synthesis of IPCC and IPBES Reports. WWF International.
Retrieved from https://wwfeu.awsassets.panda.org/down-
loads/wwf_climate__nature_and_our_1_5c_future_report.
pdf
45 Jackson, T. (2017). Prosperity without Growth: Founda-
tions for the Economy of Tomorrow (2nd ed.). London; New
York: Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group
46 Richters, O., & Siemoneit A. (2019). Growth Impera-
tives: Substantiating a Contested Concept. Structural Change
and Economic Dynamics, 51, 126–37. DOI https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.strueco.2019.07.012
89
Content
90
47 Hirschman, D., & Berman, E. (2014). Do Economists
Make Policies? On the Political Effects of Economics.
Socio-Economic Review, 12(4), 779–811. Retrieved from
https://doi.org/10.1093/ser/mwu017.
48 Johnson, T. (2011).
49 MacKenzie, D. (2006). An Engine, Not a Camera: How
Financial Models Shape Markets. Cambridge: MIT Press
50 Samuelson, P. (1990). Foreword. In P. Saunder &
W. Walstad (Ed.) The Principles of Economics Course: A
Handbook for Instructors. New York: McGraw-Hill
51 Philipsen, D. (2015). The Little Big Number: How GDP
Came to Rule the World and What to Do about It. Princeton:
Princeton University Press
52 Cf. Ellyatt, H. (2017). UK Finance Minister Vows
to Defend Free Market Economy against Labour. CNBC.
Retrieved from https://www.cnbc.com/2017/10/02/
uk-nance-minister-vows-to-defend-free-market-against-
labour.html
53 Babb, S., & Kentikelenis A. (2018). International
Financial Institutions as Agents of Neoliberalism. In D. Cahill
et al. (Ed.) The SAGE Handbook of Neoliberalism. Thousand
Oaks: Sage Publications
54 Vatn, A. (2020). Institutions for Sustainabil-
ity—Towards an Expanded Research Program for
Ecological Economics. Ecological Economics, 168.
Retrieved from https://ideas.repec.org/a/eee/ecolec/
v168y2020ics0921800919306706.html
55 Savvy, M. (2020). UK SME Data, Statistics & Charts.
Retrieved from https://www.merchantsavvy.co.uk/uk-sme-
data-stats-charts/ (24.09.2020)
56 Grifn, C. (2020). Margins: Estimating the Influence
of the Big Three on Shareholder Proposals. Social Science
Research Network Scholarly Paper. Retrieved from https://
papers.ssrn.com/abstract=3588031
57 Dür, A., & De Bièvre, D. (2007). The Question of Inter-
est Group Influence. Journal of Public Policy, 27(1),1–12.
Retrieved from https://www.cambridge.org/core/
journals/journal-of-public-policy/article/question-of-in-
terest-group-influence/1A7BC402954F23AD303B-
B3E77ECA5329
58 Mortensen, L., & Petersen, K. (2017). Extending
the Boundaries of Policy Coherence for Sustainable
Development: Engaging Business and Civil Society. The
Solutions Journal, 8(3). Retrieved from https://www.
thesolutionsjournal.com/article/extending-boundaries-pol-
icy-coherence-sustainable-development-engaging-busi-
ness-civil-society/
59 Walker, C., & Jackson, T. (2019). Measuring Prosper-
ity—Navigating the Options. CUSP Working Paper. Retrieved
from https://www.cusp.ac.uk/wp-content/uploads/
WP20%E2%80%94Measuring-Prosperity.pdf.
60 Scottish Government. (2020). Scottish Budget
2020–2021. Retrieved from https://www.gov.scot/publica-
tions/scottish-budget-2020-21/pages/2/ (24.09.2020)
61 Wellbeing Economy Alliance. (2019). New Zealand
Announces Wellbeing Budget. Retrieved from https://
wellbeingeconomy.org/new-zealand-announces-wellbe-
ing-budget (24.09.2020)
62 Walker, C., & Jackson, T. (2019). Measuring
Prosperity—Navigating the Options, CUSP Working Paper 20.
Guildford: University of Surrey
63 Hoekstra, R. (2019). Replacing GDP by 2030: Towards
a Common Language for the Well-Being and Sustainability
Community. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
64 Raworth, K. (2017). Doughnut Economics: Seven Ways
to Think like a 21st Century Economist. White River Junction,
Vermont: Chelsea Green Publishing
65 Meadows, Donella (2020). Leverage Points: Places to
Intervene in a System. The Academy for Systems Change.
Retrieved from http://donellameadows.org/archives/
leverage-points-places-to-intervene-in-a-system/.
66 Raworth, K. (2017). Doughnut Economics: Seven Ways
to Think like a 21st Century Economist. White River Junction,
Vermont: Chelsea Green Publishing
67 Robins, N., & McDaniels, J. (2016). Financing
the Transition: How Financial System Reform can Serve
Sustainable Development. UNEP Environment Enquiry.
Retrieved from https://wedocs.unep.org/bitstream/
handle/20.500.11822/26622/Financing_the-Transition.
pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y
68 Díaz, S. et al. (2019). The global assessment report
on biodiversity and ecosystem services. Summary for
Policymakers. IPBES. Retrieved from https://ipbes.net/sites/
default/les/inline/les/ipbes_global_assessment_report_
summary_for_policymakers.pdf
69 Rapid Transition Alliance. (2020). Buen Vivir: The
Rights of Nature in Bolivia and Ecuador. Retrieved from
https://www.rapidtransition.org/stories/the-rights-of-
nature-in-bolivia-and-ecuador/ (24.09.2020)
70 Vatn, A. (2020). Institutions for Sustainabil-
ity—Towards an Expanded Research Program for
Ecological Economics. Ecological Economics, 168.
Retrieved from https://ideas.repec.org/a/eee/ecolec/
v168y2020ics0921800919306706.html
Content
91
71 Richters, O., & Siemoneit A. (2019). Growth Impera-
tives: Substantiating a Contested Concept. Structural Change
and Economic Dynamics, 51, 126–37. DOI https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.strueco.2019.07.012
72 Jackson, T. (2017). Prosperity without Growth: Founda-
tions for the Economy of Tomorrow (2nd ed.). London; New
York: Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group
73 Dasgupta, P. (2020). The Dasgupta Review. Independ-
ent Review on the Economics of Biodiversity. UK Treasury
Interim Report. Retrieved from https://assets.publishing.
service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/
attachment_data/le/882222/The_Economics_of_Biodiver-
sity_The_Dasgupta_Review_Interim_Report.pdf
74 Committee on Climate Change. (2020). Building a
Resilient Recovery from the COVID-19 Crisis, Committee on
Climate Change (2020) Letter to Prime Minister on COVID19
Recovery
75 Jackson, T. (2017). Prosperity without Growth: Founda-
tions for the Economy of Tomorrow (2nd ed.). London; New
York: Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group
76 Allan, J., Donovan, C., & Ekins, P. (2020). A net-zero
emissions economic recovery from COVID-19. COP26
Universities Network Brieng. Retrieved from https://
spiral.imperial.ac.uk:8443/bitstream/10044/1/78707/2/
COP26%20Universities%20Network%20Brieng%20-%20
Economic%20Recovery%20from%20COVID-19.pdf
77 D’Alisa, G., Demaria F., & Kallis, G. (2015). Degrowth:
A Vocabulary for a New Era. Routledge, Taylor & Francis
Group. Retrieved from http://public.eblib.com/choice/
publicfullrecord.aspx?p=1843450
78 Barmes, D.,& Boait, F. (2020). The Tragedy of Growth.
Positive Money. Retrieved from http://positivemoney.org/
wp-content/uploads/2020/05/Positive-Money-Trage-
dy-of-Growth-Digital-Single-Pages.pdf
79 Ricketts, S., Hendricks, B., & Thomas, M. (2020).
Evergreen Action Plan. Medium. Retrieved from https://
medium.com/@sam.t.ricketts/evergreen-action-plan-
3f705ecb500a
80 Raworth, K. (2017). Doughnut Economics: Seven Ways
to Think like a 21st Century Economist. White River Junction,
Vermont: Chelsea Green Publishing.
81 Ibid
82 Weizsaecker, E., & Wijkman, A. (2018). Come
On! Capitalism, Short-Termism, Population and the Destruc-
tion of the Planet. New York: Springer-Verlag
83 Mazzucato, M. (2019). The Value of Everything: making
and taking in the global economy. London, UK: Allen Lane,
an imprint of Penguin Books
84 Franks, M. et al. (2018). Is Capital Back? The Role of
Land Ownership and Savings behaviour. International Tax
and Public Finance, 25(5), 1252–1276. Retrieved from
https://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s10797-018-
9486-3
85 Raworth, K. (2017). Doughnut Economics: Seven Ways
to Think like a 21st Century Economist. White River Junction,
Vermont: Chelsea Green Publishing
86 McKay, A. M. (2018). Fundraising for Favors? Linking
Lobbyist-Hosted Fundraisers to Legislative Benets. Political
Research Quarterly, 71 (4), 869-880. Retrieved from https://
journals.sagepub.com/doi/10.1177/1065912918771745
87 Richters, O., & Siemoneit A. (2019). Growth Impera-
tives: Substantiating a Contested Concept. Structural Change
and Economic Dynamics, 51, 126–37. Retrieved from
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.strueco.2019.07.012
88 Parrique, T. (2019). The Political Economy of Degrowth.
Economics and Finance. Clermont; Stockholm: Université
Clermont Auvergne; Stockholms Universitet. Retrieved from
https://tel.archives-ouvertes.fr/tel-02499463/document.
89 Raworth, K. (2017). Doughnut Economics: Seven Ways
to Think like a 21st Century Economist. White River Junction,
Vermont: Chelsea Green Publishing
90 Mazzucato, M. (2019). The Value of Everything: making
and taking in the global economy. London, UK:Allen Lane, an
imprint of Penguin Books
91 Felber, C.,& Hagelberg, G. (2017). The Economy for
the Common Good. Retrieved from https://thenextsystem.
org/the-economy-for-the-common-good (24.08.2020)
92 Ibid
93 D’Alisa, G., Demaria F., & Kallis, G.(2015). Degrowth:
A Vocabulary for a New Era. Routledge, Taylor & Francis
Group. Retrieved from http://public.eblib.com/choice/
publicfullrecord.aspx?p=1843450
94 Ibid
95 Mortensen, L., & Petersen, K. (2017). Extending
the Boundaries of Policy Coherence for Sustainable
Development: Engaging Business and Civil Society. The
Solutions Journal, 8(3). Retrieved from https://www.
thesolutionsjournal.com/article/extending-boundaries-pol-
icy-coherence-sustainable-development-engaging-busi-
ness-civil-society/
96 Richards, J., & Gastil, R. (2013). Making Direct
Democracy Deliberative through Random Assemblies.
Politics & Society, 41(2), 253-281. Retrieved from
https://ezproxy-prd.bodleian.ox.ac.uk:2262/doi/
full/10.1177/0032329213483109.
Content
92
97 United Nations Conference on Trade and Develop-
ment. (2014). Investing in the SDGs: An Action Plan. New
York: United Nations
98 United Nations Conference on Trade and Develop-
ment. (2019). Special Economic Zones. New York: United
Nations
99 Matikainen, S., Campiglio, E., & Zenghelis, D. (2017).
The Climate Impact of Quantitative Easing. Grantham
Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment,
London School of Economics and Political Science
100 Rainforest Action Network. (2020). Banking on Cli-
mate Change. San Francisco: Fossil Fuel Finance Report 2020
101 Nikolaidi, M. (2019). Greening the UK nancial 
system. Retrieved from https://www.common-wealth.co.uk/
reports/greening-the-uk-nancial-system (24.9.2020)
102 Bank of England (2018). Transition in Thinking:
The Impact of Climate Change on the UK Banking Sector.
Retrieved from https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/-/media/
boe/les/prudential-regulation/report/transition-in-
thinking-the-impact-of-climate-change-on-the-uk-banking-
sector.pdf (24.092020)
103 Gardner, B. (2015). The Cost of Inaction. Economist
Intelligence Unit Report. Retrieved from https://eiuper-
spectives.economist.com/sustainability/cost-inaction
(24.09.2020)
104 Johnson, J. et al. (2020). Global Futures: Modelling
the Global Economic Impacts of Environmental Change to
Support Policy-Making. WWF Technical Report. Retrieved
from https://www.wwf.org.uk/globalfutures (24.09.2020)
105 United Nations Environment Programme, UNEP
Finance Initiative and Global Canopy. (2020). Beyond
Business as Usual: Biodiversity targets and nance. Man-
aging biodiversity risks across business sectors. Cambridge,
UK: UNEP - WCMC
106 Bolton, P. et al. (2020). The Green Swan: Central
Banking and Financial Stability in the Age of Climate Change.
Banque de France. Retrieved from https://www.bis.org/
publ/othp31.pdf
107 Chenet, H, Ryan-Collins, J., & van Lerven, F. (2019).
Climate-Related Financial Policy in a World of Radical
Uncertainty: Towards a Precautionary Approach. SSRN
Electronic Journal. Retrieved from https://www.ssrn.com/
abstract=3520224.
108 On the insufciency of disclosure cf. k Christophers,
B. (2017). Climate Change and Financial Instability: Risk
Disclosure and the Problematics of Neoliberal Governance.
Annals of the American Association of Geographers 107(5),
1108–1127. Retrieved from https://www.tandfonline.com/
doi/abs/10.1080/24694452.2017.1293502
109 Carney, M. (2015). Breaking the Tragedy of the
Horizon – climate change and nancial stability. Speech
given at Lloyd’s of London, 29, 220–230. Retrieved from
https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/speech/2015/break-
ing-the-tragedy-of-the-horizon-climate-change-and-nan-
cial-stability
110 Naqvi, M. et al. (2017). All Swans Are Black in the
Dark. How the Shortterm Focus of Financial Analysis Does
Not Shed Light on Long Term Risks. Tragedy of the Horizon
Programme. Retrieved from http://tragedyofthehorizon.
com/All-Swans-Are-Black-in-the-Dark.pdf
111 European Securities and Markets Authority. (2019).
Report, short-term pressure on corporations. Retrieved from
http://tragedyofthehorizon.com/All-Swans-Are-Black-in-
the-Dark.pdf (24.09.2020)
112 Thomä, J. et al. (2014). Optimal Diversication and 
the Energy Transition: Impact of Equity Benchmarks on
Portfolio Diversication and Climate Finance. 2° investing 
initiative. Retrieved from https://2degrees-investing.
org/wp-content/uploads/2017/04/Optimal-diversica-
tion-and-the-energy-transition-impact-of-equity-bench-
marks-on-portfolio-diversication-and-climate--
nance-2014.pd
113 Petry, J., Fichtner, J., & Heemskerk, E. (2019).
Steering Capital: The Growing Private Authority of Index
Providers in the Age of Passive Asset Management. Review of
International Political Economy 0(0), 1–25
114 Sullivan, R. (2015). Fiduciary Duty in the 21st Century.
UNEP Finance Initiative.Retrieved from http://dx.doi.
org/10.2139/ssrn.2724866
115 Suttor-Sorel, L., & Hercelin, N. (2020). Nature’s
Return Embedding Environmental Goals at the Heart of
Economic and Financial Decision-Making. Finance Watch
Report. 33. Retrieved from https://www.nance-watch.org/
wp-content/uploads/2020/05/Natures-Return_Finance-
Watch-Report_May2020.pdf
116 Temple-West, P. (2019). Companies struggle to digest
alphabet soup of ESG arbiters. Financial Times. Retrieved
from https://www.ft.com/content/b9bdd50c-f669-3f9c-
a5f4-c2cf531a35b5 (24.09.2020)
117 The Economist. (2019). Climate Change Has Made
ESG a Force in Investing. Retrieved from https://www.econ-
omist.com/nance-and-economics/2019/12/07/climate-
change-has-made-esg-a-force-in-investing (24.09.2020)
118 International Monetary Fund. (2019). Chapter 6:
Sustainable Finance. In International Monetary Fund. Global
Financial Stability Report October. Washington, DC
119 Task Force on Nature-related Financial Disclosures.
Retrieved from https://tnfd.info/
Content
93
120 Van Toor, J. et al. (2020). Indebted to nature:
Exploring biodiversity risks for the Dutch nancial sector. De
Nederlandse Bank. Retrieved from https://www.dnb.nl/en/
binaries/Indebted%20to%20nature%20_tcm47-389172.
pdf
121 Brett, C. (2017). Climate Change and Financial
Instability: Risk Disclosure and the Problematics of
Neoliberal Governance. Annals of the American Association
of Geographers, 107(5), 1108–27. Retrieved from https://
www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/24694452.2017.
1293502
122 Philipponnat, T. (2020). Breaking the Climate-Fi-
nance Doom Loop. Brussels: Finance Watch Report
123 Campiglio, E. (2016). Beyond Carbon Pricing: The
Role of Banking and Monetary Policy in Financing the Tran-
sition to a Low-Carbon Economy. Ecological Economics 121,
220–230. Retrieved fromnhttp://eprints.lse.ac.uk/65146/1/
Beyond%20carbon%20pricing.pdf
124 De Goede, M. (2005). Virtue, fortune and faith: a
genealogy of nance. Minneapolis, Minn: University of
Minnesota Press
125 Dikau, S., & Volz, U. (2020). Central Bank Mandates,
Sustainability Objectives and the Promotion of Green
Finance. SOAS Department of Economics Working Paper
(No. 232). London, UK: SOAS University of London
126 Ibid
127 Berry, C., Laycock, A., Nash R., & Nicholls, M.
(2018). The Regulatory Compass towards a Purpose-Driven
Approach to Financial Regulation. The Financial Innovation
Lab. Retrieved from https://nanceinnovationlab.org/
wp-content/uploads/2018/06/Regulatory-Compass.pdf
128 Suttor-Sorel, L., & Hercelin, N. (2020). Nature’s
Return Embedding Environmental Goals at the Heart of
Economic and Financial Decision-Making. Finance Watch
Report. 33. Retrieved from https://www.nance-watch.org/
wp-content/uploads/2020/05/Natures-Return_Finance-
Watch-Report_May2020.pdf
129 Aviva. (2017). Delivering the Sustainable Financial
System the World Needs. A Report by Aviva. Retrieved from
le:///C:/Users/sarah/AppData/Local/Temp/2363_8_Global_
policy_report_v3.pdf
130 Network for Greening the Financial System. ( 2019).
A Call for Action, Climate Change as a Source of Financial
Risk. NGFS, First comprehensive report. Retrieved from
https://www.ngfs.net/sites/default/les/medias/docu-
ments/ngfs_rst_comprehensive_report_-_17042019_0.
pdf.
131 Bluet, H., & Ionescu, C. (2019). Into the Wild.
Integrating Nature into Investment Strategies. WWF Report,
WWF France and AXA. Retrieved from https://wwfeu.
awsassets.panda.org/downloads/report_wwf_france___
axa_into_the_wild_may_2019__dv.pdf
132 Robins, N., & McDaniels, J. (2016). Financing the
Transition – How Financial SystemReform Can Serve Sustain-
able Development. UNEP Inquiry into a sustainable nancial
system. Retrieved from http://unepinquiry.org/wp-content/
uploads/2016/11/Financing_the-Transition_Financial_Sys-
tem_Reform.pdf
133 Bolton, P. et al. (2020). The Green Swan: Central
Banking and Financial Stability in the Age of Climate Change.
Bank for International Settlements. Retrieved from https://
www.bis.org/publ/othp31.pdf
134 Network for Greening the Financial System. ( 2019).
A Call for Action, Climate Change as a Source of Financial
Risk. NGFS, First comprehensive report. Retrieved from
https://www.ngfs.net/sites/default/les/medias/docu-
ments/ngfs_rst_comprehensive_report_-_17042019_0.
pdf.
135 Robins, N., & McDaniels, J. (2016). Financing the
Transition – How Financial SystemReform Can Serve Sustain-
able Development. UNEP Inquiry into a sustainable nancial
system. Retrieved from http://unepinquiry.org/wp-content/
uploads/2016/11/Financing_the-Transition_Financial_Sys-
tem_Reform.pdf
136 Ibid
137 Aviva. (2017). Delivering the Sustainable Financial
System the World Needs. A Report by Aviva. Retrieved from
le:///C:/Users/sarah/AppData/Local/Temp/2363_8_Global_
policy_report_v3.pdf
138 Bolton, P. et al. (2020). The Green Swan: Central
Banking and Financial Stability in the Age of Climate Change.
Bank for International Settlements. Retrieved from https://
www.bis.org/publ/othp31.pdf
139 Ibid
140 Aldersgate Group. (2019). Using TCFDs to Manage
Climate Risk: Next Steps for UK Government, Investors and
Businesses. Retrieved from https://www.aldersgategroup.
org.uk/asset/1519 (24.09.2020)
141 Task Force on Nature-related Financial Disclosures.
Retrieved from https://www.fsb-tcfd.org/tcfd-supporters/
142 Tornero, C. (2020). DWP eyes TCFD framework for UK
workplace pensions law. Responsible Investor. Retrieved
from https://www.responsible-investor.com/articles/
dwp-eyes-tcfd-framework-for-uk-workplace-pensions-law
(24.09.2020)
Content
94
143 When we speak about business, we are referring
to non-government entities who make money through
commercial exchange. Inclusive of this denition are
not-for-prots such as cooperatives, Community Interest
Companies (CICs) and social enterprises.
144 Future-Fit Business Benchmark. (2020). The Positive
Pursuit Guide (Release 2.2.). London: Future Fit Foundation
145 Department for Business, Energy and Industrial
Strategy. (2018). 2018 UK Greenhouse Gas Emissions,
Final Figures. Crown. Retrieved from https://assets.
publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/
uploads/attachment_data/le/862887/2018_Final_green-
house_gas_emissions_statistical_release.pdf
146 Watson, B. (2020). Dataset EMP13: Employment
by industry. Ofce for National Statistics. Retrieved from
https://www.ons.gov.uk/employmentandlabourmarket/
peopleinwork/employmentandemployeetypes/datasets/
employmentbyindustryemp13 (24.09.2020)
147 Department for Business, Energy and Industrial
Strategy. (2018). 2018 UK Greenhouse Gas Emissions,
Final Figures. Crown. Retrieved from https://assets.
publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/
uploads/attachment_data/le/862887/2018_Final_green-
house_gas_emissions_statistical_release.pdf
148 Watson, B. (2020). Dataset EMP13: Employment
by industry. Ofce for National Statistics. Retrieved from
https://www.ons.gov.uk/employmentandlabourmarket/
peopleinwork/employmentandemployeetypes/datasets/
employmentbyindustryemp13 (24.09.2020)
149 Sabanoglu, T. (2019). Total consumer spending
2005–2019. Statista. Retrieved from https://www.statista.
com/statistics/368665/consumer-expenditure-united-king-
dom-uk/ (24.09.2020)
150 Wellbeing Economy Alliance. (2020). The Business
of Wellbeing. Retrieved from https://wellbeingeconomy.org/
wp-content/uploads/2020/01/The-Business-of-Wellbeing-
guide-Web.pdf
151 Silk, D. M., Katz, D. A., & Niles, S. V. (2020). U.K.
and EU Regulators Move Ahead on ESG Disclosures and
Benchmarks. Harvard Law School Forum on Corporate
Governance. Retrieved from https://corpgov.law.harvard.
edu/2020/04/26/u-k-and-eu-regulators-move-ahead-on-
esg-disclosures-and-benchmarks/
152 GOV.UK. (2020). Carrier bag charges: Retailers
responsibilities. Crown. Retrieved from https://www.gov.
uk/guidance/carrier-bag-charges-retailers-responsibilities
(24.09.2020)
153 Department for Business, Energy and Industrial
Strategy. (2019). 2018 UK Greenhouse gas emissions,
provisional gures. Crown. Retrieved from https://assets.
publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/
uploads/attachment_data/le/790626/2018-provision-
al-emissions-statistics-report.pdf
154 Department for Environment, Food and Rural
Affairs. (2020). UK Statistics on Waste. Government Statisti-
cal Service. Retrieved from https://assets.publishing.service.
gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_
data/le/918270/UK_Statistics_on_Waste_statistical_
notice_March_2020_accessible_FINAL_updated_size_12.
pdf
155 Evans, S. (2020). Analysis: UK’s CO
2
emissions have
fallen 29 % over the past decade. Carbon Brief. Retrieved
from https://www.carbonbrief.org/analysis-uks-co2-
emissions-have-fallen-29-per-cent-over-the-past-decade
(24.09.2020)
156 Santarius, T. (2016). Investigating meso-economic
rebound effects: production-side effects and feedback loops
between the micro and macro level. Journal of Cleaner
Production 134, 406-413. Retrieved from https://doi.
org/10.1016/J.JCLEPRO.2015.09.055
157 Woodyatt, K. (2019). Navigator Report 2019. HSBC.
Retrieved from https://www.business.hsbc.com/navigator
(24.09.2020)
158 Wellbeing Economy Alliance. (2020). The Business
of Wellbeing. Retrieved from https://wellbeingeconomy.org/
wp-content/uploads/2020/01/The-Business-of-Wellbeing-
guide-Web.pdf
159 United Nations Development Program, Global
Ethical Finance Initiative, & R.J. Fleming&Co (2020).
Mobilising Private Sector Capital in Support of the UN Sus-
tainable Development Goals. Retrieved from https://www.
globalethicalnance.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/04/
Mobilising-Private-Sector-Capital-in-Support-of-the-SDGs-
GEFI_RJ-FLeming-Report.pdf
160 Ibid
161 Ibid
162 Further ideas for taxation are related to decreasing
power imbalances and can be found in the chapter on policy.
163 Raworth, K. (2017). Doughnut Economics: Seven
Ways to Think like a 21st Century Economist. White River
Junction, Vermont: Chelsea Green Publishing
164 Ibid
165 Ibid
Content
95
166 Lipton, M. et al. (2018). The Future of the
Corporation. Harvard Law School Forum on Corporate
Governance. Retrieved from https://corpgov.law.
harvard.edu/2018/11/07/the-future-of-the-corporation/
(24.09.2020)
167 Weizsaecker, E., & Wijkman, A. (2018). Come
On! Capitalism, Short-Termism, Population and the Destruc-
tion of the Planet. New York: Springer-Verlag
168 Ibid
169 Various ideas related to channelling public and
private investments have already been summarized in the
respective policy and nance chapter (crossref).
170 United Nations Development Program, Global
Ethical Finance Initiative, & R. J. Fleming & Co (2020).
Mobilising Private Sector Capital in Support of the UN Sus-
tainable Development Goals. Retrieved from https://www.
globalethicalnance.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/04/
Mobilising-Private-Sector-Capital-in-Support-of-the-SDGs-
GEFI_RJ-FLeming-Report.pdf
171 Stouthuysen, P., & le Roy, D. (2010). Cradle to
Cradle: Theoretical Framework. Netherlands C2C-Center.
Retrieved from http://www.c2c-centre.com/sites/default/
les/C2C%20Network%20-%20C2C%20theor%20
framework.pdf
172 Raworth, K. (2017). Doughnut Economics: Seven
Ways to Think like a 21st Century Economist. White River
Junction, Vermont: Chelsea Green Publishing
173 European Environment Agency. (2019). Textiles
and the environment in a circular economy. Retrieved from
https://www.eea.europa.eu/themes/waste/resource-ef-
ciency/textiles-in-europe-s-circular-economy (24.09.2020)
174 Barmes, D., & Boait, F. (2020). The Tragedy of Growth.
Positive Money. Retrieved from http://positivemoney.org/
wp-content/uploads/2020/05/Positive-Money-Trage-
dy-of-Growth-Digital-Single-Pages.pdf
175 Wellbeing Economy Alliance. (2020). The Business
of Wellbeing. Retrieved from https://wellbeingeconomy.org/
wp-content/uploads/2020/01/The-Business-of-Wellbeing-
guide-Web.pdf
176 Institute for Global Environmental Strategies, Aalto
University, & D-mat Itd. (2019). 1.5-Degree Lifestyles:
Targets and Options for Reducing Lifestyle Carbon Footprints.
Hayama, Japan: Institute for Global Environmental
Strategies
177 Ibid
178 Seyfang, G. (2009). The New Economics of Sustain-
able Consumption: Seeds of Change. Basingstoke, England;
New York: Palgrave Macmillan
179 Ivanova, D. et al. (2016). Environmental Impact
Assessment of Household Consumption: Environmental
Impact Assessment of Household Consumption. Journal of
Industrial Ecology 20(3), 526–536. Retrieved from https://
onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/pdf/10.1111/jiec.12371?-
casa_token=Oyak1h5skiwAAAAA:Ln_XfTd0ua9RfnRaiC-
q6tNr3gWDDB37M__APnRzeVUjjWtbIfqegXyRHtymD2LdO-
VbYOoSSXcSKkF0ew-Q
180 Jackson, T. (2017). Prosperity without Growth: Foun-
dations for the Economy of Tomorrow (2nd ed.). London;
New York: Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group
181 Parrique, T. et al. (2019). Decoupling Debunked:
Evidence and Arguments against Green Growth as a Sole
Strategy for Sustainability. European Environmental Bureau.
Retrieved from https://mk0eeborgicuypctuf7e.kinstacdn.
com/wp-content/uploads/2019/07/Decoupling-Debunked.
pdf
182 Shove, Elizabeth (2010). Beyond the ABC: Climate
Change Policy and Theories of Social Change. Environment
and Planning A: Economy and Space, 42(6), 1273–1285.
Retrieved from https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/10.1068/
a42282
183 Jackson, T. (2017). Prosperity without Growth: Foun-
dations for the Economy of Tomorrow (2nd ed.). London;
New York: Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group
184 Büchs, M., & Koch M. (2017). Postgrowth and
Wellbeing: Challenges to Sustainable Welfare. Palgrave
Macmillan. Retrieved from https://www.palgrave.com/gp/
book/9783319599021
185 Dietz, R., & O’Neill, D. W. (2013). Enough Is
Enough: Building a Sustainable Economy in a World of
Finite Resources (1st ed.). San Francisco: Berrett-Koehler
Publishers
186 Steinberger, J. K., Lamb, W. F., & Sakai M. (2020).
Your Money or Your Life? The Carbon-Development Paradox.
Environmental Research Letters, 15(4) Retrieved from
10.1088/1748-9326/ab7461
187 Jackson, T. (2017). Prosperity without Growth: Foun-
dations for the Economy of Tomorrow (2nd ed.). London;
New York: Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group
188 Kasser, T., & Kanner A.D. (Eds.). (2004). Psychology
and Consumer Culture: The Struggle for a Good Life in a
Materialistic World. Washington, DC: American Psychologi-
cal Association
189 Parrique, T. (2019). The Political Economy of
Degrowth. Economics and Finance. Clermont; Stockholm:
Université Clermont Auvergne; Stockholms Universitet.
Content
96
190 Committee on Climate Change. (2020). Building a
Resilient Recovery from the COVID-19 Crisis. Retrieved from
https://d423d1558e1d71897434.b-cdn.net/wp-content/
uploads/2020/05/CCC-to-Prime-Minister-Boris-Johnson-
Covid-19-recovery-002.pdf
191 New Climate Institute, & Climate Analytics. (2020).
A Government Roadmap for Addressing the Climate and
Post COVID-19 Economic Crises. Climate Action Tracker.
Retrieved from https://climateactiontracker.org/docu-
ments/706/CAT_2020-04-27_Brieng_COVID19_Apr2020.
pdf
192 Ricketts, S., Hendricks B., & Thomas, M. (2020).
Evergreen Action Plan. Medium. Retrieved from https://
medium.com/@sam.t.ricketts/evergreen-action-plan-
3f705ecb500a (24.09.2020)
193 Ferguson, P. (2013). Post-Growth Policy Instruments.
International Journal of Green Economics, 7(4), 405–421
194 Schneidewind, U., & Zahrnt, A. (2013). Damit gutes
Leben einfacher wird: Perspektiven einer Sufzienzpolitik.
München, Germany: Oekom Verlag
195 Hirsch, F. (1978). Social Limits to Growth (2nd ed.).
London, UK: Routledge
196 Siemoneit, A. (2019). An Offer You Can’t Refuse:
Enhancing Personal Productivity through Efciency 
Consumption. Technology in Society, 59. Retrieved from
https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/abs/pii/
S0160791X18301386?via%3Dihub
197 Raworth, Kate. 2017. Doughnut Economics: Seven
Ways to Think like a 21st Century Economist. White River
Junction, Vermont: Chelsea Green Publishing
198 Mazzucato, M. (2019). The Value of Everything:
making and taking in the global economy. London, UK:Allen
Lane, an imprint of Penguin Books
199 Roberts, R. (2018). Climate Change: The Antidote To
Democracy’s Mid-Life Crisis. Medium. Retrieved from https://
medium.com/volans/climate-change-the-antidote-to-
democracys-mid-life-crisis-a486305ef429 (24.09.2020)
200 Weizsaecker, E.,& Wijkman, A. (2018). Come On!
Capitalism, Short-Termism, Population and the Destruction
of the Planet. New York: Springer-Verlag
201 Schneidewind, U., & Zahrnt, A. (2013). Damit gutes
Leben einfacher wird: Perspektiven einer Sufzienzpolitik.
München, Germany: Oekom Verlag
202 Ibid
203 Ibid
204 Díaz, S. et al. (2019). Summary for Policymakers of
the Global Assessment Report on Biodiversity and Ecosystem
Services. Intergovernmental Science-Policy Platform on
Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services. Retrieved from https://
zenodo.org/record/3553579
205 Parrique, T. (2019). The Political Economy of
Degrowth. Economics and Finance. Clermont; Stockholm:
Université Clermont Auvergne; Stockholms Universitet
206 Schneidewind, U., & Zahrnt, A. (2013). Damit gutes
Leben einfacher wird: Perspektiven einer Sufzienzpolitik.
München, Germany: Oekom Verlag
207 Petschow, U. et al. (2018). Gesellschaftliches
Wohlergehen innerhalb planetarer Grenzen, Der Ansatz einer
vorsorgeorientierten Postwachstumsposition. Umweltbun-
desamt. Retrieved from https://www.umweltbundesamt.de/
publikationen/vorsorgeorientierte-postwachstumsposition
208 Ibid
209 Cosme, I., Santos R., & O’Neill, D. W. (2017).
Assessing the Degrowth Discourse: A Review and Analysis
of Academic Degrowth Policy Proposals. Journal of Cleaner
Production, 149, 321–34. Retrieved from https://www.
researchgate.net/publication/313326676_Assessing_
the_degrowth_discourse_A_review_and_analysis_of_aca-
demic_degrowth_policy_proposals
210 Raworth, K. (2017). Doughnut Economics: Seven
Ways to Think like a 21st Century Economist. White River
Junction, Vermont: Chelsea Green Publishing
211 D’Alisa, G., Demaria F., & Kallis, G. (2015). Degrowth:
A Vocabulary for a New Era. Routledge, Taylor & Francis
Group. Retrieved from http://public.eblib.com/choice/
publicfullrecord.aspx?p=1843450
212 Ferguson, P. (2013). Post-Growth Policy Instruments.
International Journal of Green Economics, 7(4), 405-421.
Retrieved from https://www.researchgate.net/publica-
tion/264437715_Post-growth_policy_instruments
213 Raworth, K. (2017). Doughnut Economics: Seven
Ways to Think like a 21st Century Economist. White River
Junction, Vermont: Chelsea Green Publishing
214 Díaz, S. et al. (2019). The global assessment report
on biodiversity and ecosystem services. Summary for
Policymakers. IPBES. Retrieved from https://ipbes.net/sites/
default/les/inline/les/ipbes_global_assessment_report_
summary_for_policymakers.pdf
215 Jackson, T. (2017). Prosperity without Growth: Foun-
dations for the Economy of Tomorrow (2nd ed.). London;
New York: Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group
Content
97
216 Schneidewind, U., & Zahrnt, A. (2013). Damit gutes
Leben einfacher wird: Perspektiven einer Sufzienzpolitik.
München, Germany: Oekom Verlag
217 Petschow, U. et al. (2018). Gesellschaftliches
Wohlergehen innerhalb planetarer Grenzen, Der Ansatz einer
vorsorgeorientierten Postwachstumsposition. Umweltbun-
desamt. Retrieved from https://www.umweltbundesamt.de/
publikationen/vorsorgeorientierte-postwachstumsposition
218 Schneidewind, U., & Zahrnt, A. (2013). Damit gutes
Leben einfacher wird: Perspektiven einer Sufzienzpolitik.
München, Germany: Oekom Verlag
219 Ibid
220 Petschow, U. et al. (2018). Gesellschaftliches
Wohlergehen innerhalb planetarer Grenzen, Der Ansatz einer
vorsorgeorientierten Postwachstumsposition. Umweltbun-
desamt. Retrieved from https://www.umweltbundesamt.de/
publikationen/vorsorgeorientierte-postwachstumsposition
221 D’Alisa, G., Demaria F., & Kallis, G. (2015). Degrowth:
A Vocabulary for a New Era. Routledge, Taylor & Francis
Group. Retrieved from http://public.eblib.com/choice/
publicfullrecord.aspx?p=1843450
222 Felber, C.,& Hagelberg, G. (2017). The Economy for
the Common Good. Retrieved from https://thenextsystem.
org/the-economy-for-the-common-good (24.09.2020)
223 Petschow, U. et al. (2018). Gesellschaftliches
Wohlergehen innerhalb planetarer Grenzen, Der Ansatz einer
vorsorgeorientierten Postwachstumsposition. Umweltbun-
desamt. Retrieved from https://www.umweltbundesamt.de/
publikationen/vorsorgeorientierte-postwachstumsposition
224 D’Alisa, G., Demaria F., & Kallis, G. (2015). Degrowth:
A Vocabulary for a New Era. Routledge, Taylor & Francis
Group. Retrieved from http://public.eblib.com/choice/
publicfullrecord.aspx?p=1843450
225 Parrique, T. (2019). The Political Economy of
Degrowth. Economics and Finance. Clermont; Stockholm:
Université Clermont Auvergne; Stockholms Universitet.
Retrieved from https://tel.archives-ouvertes.fr/tel-
02499463/document
226 D’Alisa, G., Demaria F., & Kallis, G. (2015). Degrowth:
A Vocabulary for a New Era. Routledge, Taylor & Francis
Group. Retrieved from http://public.eblib.com/choice/
publicfullrecord.aspx?p=1843450
227 Roberts, R. (2018). Climate Change: The Antidote To
Democracy’s Mid-Life Crisis. Medium. Retrieved from https://
medium.com/volans/climate-change-the-antidote-to-
democracys-mid-life-crisis-a486305ef429 (24.09.2020)
228 Robins, N., & McDaniels, J. (2016). Financing
the Transition: How Financial System Reform can Serve
Sustainable Development. UNEP Environment Enquiry.
Retrieved from https://wedocs.unep.org/bitstream/
handle/20.500.11822/26622/Financing_the-Transition.
pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y
229 HM Treasury. (2020). The Dasgupta Review – Inde-
pendent Review on the Economics of Biodiversity, Interim
Report, Crown. Retrieved from https://assets.publishing.
service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/
attachment_data/le/882222/The_Economics_of_Biodiver-
sity_The_Dasgupta_Review_Interim_Report.pdf
230 For example, $NZ1 billion deployed to improve the
countrys rail network; support for farmers to use land more
sustainably; $NZ25 million for research aimed at driving
down emissions from agriculture (currently accounting for
around half of New Zealand’s greenhouse gases); $NZ20
million for energy technology research; and $4m for
improving recycling and resource recovery in pursuit of a
zero waste economy.
231 Stark, C. et al. (2019). Net Zero – Technical Report.
Committee on Climate Change. Retrieved from https://www.
theccc.org.uk/publication/net-zero-technical-report/
232 Greenpeace. (2019). Government investment for
a greener and fairer economy. Retrieved from https://
www.greenpeace.org.uk/wp-content/uploads/2019/08/
Government-Investment-for-a-greener-and-fairer-econo-
my-FINAL-30.08.19.pdf
233 Financial Times. (2020). Rishi Sunak should abandon
arbitrary scal rules. Retrieved from https://www.ft.com/
content/38845250-53c5-11ea-a1ef-da1721a0541e
(24.09.2020)
234 Ecuity. (2020). Local green jobs- accelerating a
sustainable economic recovery. Local Governments Associ-
ation. Retrieved from https://www.ecuity.com/wp-content/
uploads/2020/06/Local-green-jobs-accelerating-a-sustain-
able-economic-recovery_nal.pdf
235 Lyons, G., Lightfoot W., Zeber, J. (2020). A pro
growth economic strategy. Policy Exchange. Retrieved from
https://policyexchange.org.uk/wp-content/uploads/A-pro-
growth-economic-strategy.pdf
236 Mazzucato, M., & Macfarlane, L. (2019). A mission
oriented framework for the Scottish national investment
bank. Institute for innovation and public purpose. Retrieved
from https://www.ucl.ac.uk/bartlett/public-purpose/sites/
public-purpose/les/mission-oriented-framework-for-snib_
nal.pdf
237 Omarova, S. T. (2020). Why We Need a National
Investment Authority. Cornell Legal Studies Research Paper
No. 20-34. Retrieved from http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/
ssrn.3566462
Content
98
238 Macfarlane, L., Mazzucato, M. (2018). State
investment banks and patient nance: An international 
comparison (Working Paper IIPP WP 2018–01). Institute for
innovation and public purpose. Retrieved from https://www.
ucl.ac.uk/bartlett/public-purpose/sites/public-purpose/
les/iipp_wp_2018-01.pdf
239 European Investment Bank. (2019). EU Bank
launches ambitious new climate strategy and Energy Lend-
ing Policy. Retrieved from https://www.eib.org/en/press/
all/2019-313-eu-bank-launches-ambitious-new-climate-
strategy-and-energy-lending-policy (24.09.2020)
240 Financial Times. (2020). UK ministers plan Green
Investment Bank 2.0. Retrieved from https://www.ft.com/
content/3350252b-6511-415d-9c19-e03351f646f9
(24.09.2020)
241 Billington, P., Smith C. A., & Ball, M. (2020).
Accelerating the rate of investment in local energy projects.
UK100. Retrieved from https://www.uk100.org/wp-content/
uploads/2020/06/Local-Energy-Insight-Summary-Re-
port-July-2020.pdf
242 The Climate Coalition. (2020). The plan
for a green, fair and healthy recovery. Retrieved
from https://static1.squarespace.com/
static/58b40fe1be65940cc4889d33/t/5eec99
dff809127782261619/1592564208100/Green+recov-
ery+plan+nal+1.pdf
243 RSA Food, Farming and Countryside Commission.
(2019). Our future in the land. Retrieved from https://www.
thersa.org/globalassets/reports/rsa-ffcc-our-future-in-the-
land.pdf
244 At a global level the supervision of banks’ risk assess-
ments is carried out according to the Basel Accords, which
are implemented into national legislation. The Basel Accord
(i.e. Basel III currently) consists of three pillars.
245 Cf. Bank for International Settlements 2019.
246 Cf. Bank of England. (2019). Enhancing banks’ and
insurers’ approaches to managing the nancial risks from 
climate change, Supervisory Statement 3/19. Retrieved from
https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/prudential-regulation/
publication/2019/enhancing-banks-and-insurers-ap-
proaches-to-managing-the-nancial-risks-from-climate-
change-ss
247 Van Lerven, F. (2018). Brieng Note: The Bank of 
England and a 1.5°C Green Transition: Re-Shaping Finance.
New Economic Foundation. Retrieved from https://neweco-
nomics.org/uploads/les/reshaping-nance.pdf
248 Wang, F., Yang, S., Reisner, A., & Liu N. (2019). Does
Green Credit PolicyWork in China? The Correlation between
Green Credit and Corporate Environmental Information
Disclosure Quality. MDPI, Open Access Journal, 11(3), 1-15.
249 Bezemer, D., Ryan-Collins, J., Van Lerven, F., &
Zhang, Lu. (2018). Credit where it’s due: A historical, theo-
retical and empirical review of credit guidance policies in the
20th century (Working Paper IIPP WP 2018–11). Institute
for Innovation and Public Purpose. Retrieved from https://
www.ucl.ac.uk/bartlett/public-purpose/sites/public-pur-
pose/les/iipp-wp-2018-11_credit_where_its_due.pdf
250 Yannis Dafermos, et al (2020). Decarbonising the
Bank of England’s Pandemic QE, Retrieved from https://
neweconomics.org/uploads/les/NEF-Decarbonise-BoE-re-
port.pdf
251 The ECB’s primary objective is price stability, but it is
required to implement this objective in a way that also takes
into account the broader objectives of the European Union.
See: European Central Bank. (2020). Objective of monetary
policy. Retrieved from https://www.ecb.europa.eu/mopo/
intro/objective/html/index.en.html
252 Financial Times. Lagarde puts green policy top of
agenda in ECB bond buying. Retrieved from https://www.
ft.com/content/f776ea60-2b84-4b72-9765-2c084b-
ff6e32; also to the existing gaps for green investments
(24.09.2020)
253 Network for Greening the Financial System. (2018).
A call for action Climate change as a source of nancial 
risk, First comprehensive report. Retrieved from https://
www.ngfs.net/en/rst-comprehensive-report-call-action
(23.09.2020)
254 Henry George. (1879). Progress and Poverty. New
York, USA: Sterling Publishing Company
255 Mirrlees J et al. (2011). The Mirrlees Review: Con-
clusions and Recommendations for Reform. Fiscal Studies.
32(3), 331–359. Retrieved from http://www.homepages.ucl.
ac.uk/~uctp39a/MirrleesReview_FS_2011.pdf
256 Nanda S., & Parkes H. (2019). Just Tax: Reforming
the taxation of income from wealth and work. IPPR.
Retrieved from https://www.ippr.org/research/publications/
just-tax (24.09.2020)
257 Data estimated for 2018, see: Ofce for National
Statistics. (2019). The UK national balance sheet estimates:
2019. Retrieved from https://www.ons.gov.uk/economy/
nationalaccounts/uksectoraccounts/bulletins/nationalbal-
ancesheet/2019 (24.09.2020)
258 Ibid.
259 Barnaby, C., & Pearce, N. (2017). Estimation of Land
Value Tax Revenues in London. Institute for Policy Research,
University of Bath. Retrieved from https://www.bath.ac.uk/
publications/estimation-of-land-value-tax-revenues-in-
london/attachments/ipr-estimation-of-land-value-tax-
revenues-in-london.pdf
Content
99
260 Arnold S., Krebel, L., & Stirling, A. (2019). Funding
Local Government with a Land Value Tax. New Economics
Foundation. Retrieved from https://neweconomics.
org/2019/11/funding-local-government-with-a-land-value-
tax (24.09.2020)
261 Hughes, C. et al. (2018). Investigation of Potential
Land Value Tax Policy Options for Scotland. University
of Reading for Scottish Land Commission. Retrieved
from https://landcommission.gov.scot/downloads/5d-
d6984da0491_Land-Value-Tax-Policy-Options-for-Scot-
land-Final-Report-23-7-18.pdf
262 Arnold S., Krebel, L., & Stirling, A. (2019). Funding
Local Government with a Land Value Tax. New Economics
Foundation. Retrieved from https://neweconomics.
org/2019/11/funding-local-government-with-a-land-value-
tax (24.09.2020)
263 Hughes, C. et al. (2018). Investigation of Potential
Land Value Tax Policy Options for Scotland. University
of Reading for Scottish Land Commission. Retrieved
from https://landcommission.gov.scot/downloads/5d-
d6984da0491_Land-Value-Tax-Policy-Options-for-Scot-
land-Final-Report-23-7-18.pdf
264 Mattauch, L., Siegmeier, J., Edenhofer, O., &
Creutzig, F. (2018). Financing Public Capital When Rents
Are Back: A Macroeconomic Henry George Theorem.
Finanz Archiv 74(3), 340–360. Retrieved from https://
www.mohrsiebeck.com/artikel/nancing-public-cap-
ital-when-rents-are-back-a-macroeconomic-hen-
ry-george-theorem-101628fa-2018-0011
265 Scottish Land Commission. (2018). Land Value
Tax. Retrieved from https://landcommission.gov.scot/
downloads/5dd69d3b1fba6_LAND-FOCUS_Land-Val-
ue-Tax-October-2018.pdf
266 Ibid.
267 Díaz, S. et al. (2019). Summary for Policymakers of
the Global Assessment Report on Biodiversity and Ecosystem
Services. Intergovernmental Science-Policy Platform on
Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services. Retrieved from https://
zenodo.org/record/3553579 (24.09.2020)
268 Oberle, B. et al.(2019). Global Resource Outlook
2019, Natural Resources for the Future We Want. United
Nations Environment Programme, International
Resource Panel. Retrieved from http://hdl.handle.
net/20.500.11822/27517
269 Díaz, S. et al. (2019). The global assessment report
on biodiversity and ecosystem services. Summary for
Policymakers. IPBES. Retrieved from https://ipbes.net/sites/
default/les/inline/les/ipbes_global_assessment_report_
summary_for_policymakers.pdf
270 Bringezu, S. (2015). Possible Target Corridor for
Sustainable Use of Global Material Resources. Resources
4(1), 25–54. Retrieved from https://www.mdpi.com/2079-
9276/4/1/25/htm
271 Dittrich, M et al. (2012). Green Economies around
the World? Implications of Resource Use for Development
and the Environment. Wien: Sustainable Europe Research
Institute
272 Hoekstra, A. Y., & Wiedmann, T. O. (2014).
Humanity’s Unsustainable Environmental Footprint. Science,
344(6188), 1114–1117. Retrieved from http://www.
ayhoekstra.nl/pubs/Hoekstra-Wiedmann-2014-Environ-
mentalFootprint.pdf
273 United Nations Environmental Program. (2014).
Managing and Conserving the Natural Resource Base for
Sustained Economic and Social Development. International
Resource Panel. Retrieved from http://hdl.handle.
net/20.500.11822/31527
274 Spash, C, L., & Aslaksen, I. (2015). Re-Establishing
an Ecological Discourse in the Policy Debate over How to
Value Ecosystems and Biodiversity. Journal of Environmental
Management, 159, 245–253. Retrieved from http://www.
wrongkindofgreen.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/01/2015-
Spash_Aslaksen-Ecological_discourse-JEM.pdf
275 Dietz, R., & O’Neill, D. W. (2013). Enough Is
Enough: Building a Sustainable Economy in a World of
Finite Resources (1st ed.). San Francisco: Berrett-Koehler
Publishers
276 Jackson, T. (2017). Prosperity without Growth: Foun-
dations for the Economy of Tomorrow (2nd ed.). London;
New York: Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group
277 Stratford, B. (2020). The Threat of Rent Extraction in
a Resource-Constrained Future. Ecological Economics 169.
Retrieved from https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/
article/pii/S0921800919304203
278 Rounsevell M. D. A. et al. (2020). A biodiversity
target based on species extinctions. Science,368(6496),
1193-1195. Retrieved from https://science.sciencemag.org/
content/368/6496/1193.summary
279 Corporate Europe Observatory. (2015). EU emissions
trading: 5 reasons to scrap the ETS. Retrieved from https://
corporateeurope.org/en/environment/2015/10/eu-emis-
sions-trading-5-reasons-scrap-ets
280 Ellerman, A. D., & Buchner, B. K. (2007). The Euro-
pean Union Emissions Trading Scheme: Origins, Allocation,
and Early Results. Review of Environmental Economics and
Policy, 1(1), 66–87. Retrieved from https://academic.oup.
com/reep/article/1/1/66/1548600
Content
100
281 Font Vivanco, D., Kemp R., & van der Voet E. (2016).
How to Deal with the Rebound Effect? A Policy-Oriented
Approach. Energy Policy, 94, 114–25. Retrieved from
https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/
S0301421516301586
282 OECD. (2017). Political Economy of Biodiversity Policy
Reform. OECD Publishing. Retrieved from https://www.
oecd-ilibrary.org/docserver/9789264269545-en.pdf?ex-
pires=1600871980&id=id&accname=ocid41023547&-
checksum=551B5E65EBE5DC428502B0331403643F
283 Constanza, R. et al. (2015). An Introduction to
Ecological Economics (2nd Ed.). Ecological Engineering 82.
284 Shmelev, S. (2016). Green Economy Reader:
Lectures in Ecological Economics and Sustainability.
Springer. Retrieved from https://www.researchgate.net/
publication/308697228_Green_Economy_Reader_Lec-
tures_in_Ecological_Economics_and_Sustainability
285 Aslaksen, I. et al. (2012). Knowledge Gathering and
Communication on Biodiversity: Developing the Norwegian
Nature Index. Norsk Geogrask Tidsskrift - Norwegian
Journal of Geography, 66(5), 300–308. Retrieved from
https://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/00291951.
2012.744092
286 Nybø, S., Certain G., & Skarpaas, O. (2012). The
Norwegian Nature Index – State and Trends of Biodiversity
in Norway. Norsk Geogrask Tidsskrift – Norwegian Journal
of Geography,66(5), 241–49. Retrieved from https://www.
tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/00291951.2012.7431
68
287 Heinmiller, B. T. (2007). The Politics of Cap
and Trade Policies. Natural Resources Journal, 47(2),
445–67. Retrieved from https://core.ac.uk/download/
pdf/151579961.pdf
288 Peer, G. et al. (2014). Agriculture policy. EU
agricultural reform fails on biodiversity. Science 344(6188),
1090–1092. Retrieved from https://www.researchgate.net/
publication/262886978_Agriculture_policy_EU_agricul-
tural_reform_fails_on_biodiversity
289 Stratford, B. (2020). The Threat of Rent Extraction in
a Resource-Constrained Future. Ecological Economics, 169.
Retrieved from https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/
article/pii/S0921800919304203
290 Find the report on: https://sciencebasedtargetsnet-
work.org/resources/guidance/
291 World Wide Fund For Nature. (2020). Working
with global businesses to set scientically validated goals 
to cut their emissions. Retrieved from https://wwf.panda.
org/our_work/our_focus/climate_and_energy_practice/
what_we_do/climatebusiness/science_based_targets_initi-
ative (24.09.2020)
292 Heinmiller, B. T. (2007). The Politics of Cap
and Trade Policies. Natural Resources Journal, 47(2),
445–67. Retrieved from https://core.ac.uk/download/
pdf/151579961.pdf
293 Peer, G. et al. (2014). Agriculture policy. EU
agricultural reform fails on biodiversity. Science 344(6188),
1090–1092. Retrieved from https://www.researchgate.net/
publication/262886978_Agriculture_policy_EU_agricul-
tural_reform_fails_on_biodiversity
294 Stratford, B. (2020). The Threat of Rent Extraction in
a Resource-Constrained Future. Ecological Economics, 169.
Retrieved from https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/
article/pii/S0921800919304203
295 Simoncini, R. et al. (2019). Constraints and Opportu-
nities for Mainstreaming Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services
in the EU’s Common Agricultural Policy: Insights from
the IPBES Assessment for Europe and Central Asia. Land
use Policy, 88. Retrieved from https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
landusepol.2019.104099
296 Peer, G. et al. (2014). Agriculture policy. EU
agricultural reform fails on biodiversity. Science 344(6188),
1090–1092. Retrieved from https://www.researchgate.net/
publication/262886978_Agriculture_policy_EU_agricul-
tural_reform_fails_on_biodiversity
297 Font Vivanco, D., Kemp R., & van der Voet E. (2016).
How to Deal with the Rebound Effect? A Policy-Oriented
Approach. Energy Policy, 94, 114–25. Retrieved from
https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/
S0301421516301586
298 Díaz, S. et al. (2019). Summary for Policymakers of
the Global Assessment Report on Biodiversity and Ecosystem
Services. Intergovernmental Science-Policy Platform on
Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services. Retrieved from https://
zenodo.org/record/3553579 (24.09.2020)
299 Portereld, M. C. (2019). Border Adjustments for Car-
bon Taxes, PPMs, and the WTO. University of Pennsylvania
Journal of International Law, 41(1),1–41. Retrieved from
https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/jil/vol41/iss1/2
300 Mehling, M. A. et al. (2019). Designing Border
Carbon Adjustments for Enhanced Climate Action. American
Journal of International Law, 113(3), 433–81. Retrieved
from https://www.cambridge.org/core/journals/ameri-
can-journal-of-international-law/article/designing-bor-
der-carbon-adjustments-for-enhanced-climate-action/
BF4266550F09E5E4A7479E09C047B984 (24.09.20202)
301 Moilanen, A., and Laitila, J., (2016). FORUM: Indirect
Leakage Leads to a Failure of Avoided Loss Biodiversity
Offsetting. The Journal of applied ecology, 53(1),106–111.
Retrieved from https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/
PMC4737393/
Content
101
302 Harrison, M. E., & Paoli. G. D. (2012). Managing the
Risk of Biodiversity Leakage from Prioritising REDD+ in the
Most Carbon-Rich Forests: The Case Study of Peat-Swamp
Forests in Kalimantan, Indonesia. Tropical Conservation Sci-
ence, 5(4), 426–33. Retrieved fromhttps://journals.sagepub.
com/doi/full/10.1177/194008291200500402
303 Moilanen, A., and Laitila, J., (2016). FORUM: Indirect
Leakage Leads to a Failure of Avoided Loss Biodiversity
Offsetting. The Journal of applied ecology, 53(1),106–111.
Retrieved from https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/
PMC4737393/
304 Mehling, M. A. et al. (2019). Designing Border
Carbon Adjustments for Enhanced Climate Action. American
Journal of International Law, 113(3), 433–81. Retrieved
from https://www.cambridge.org/core/journals/ameri-
can-journal-of-international-law/article/designing-bor-
der-carbon-adjustments-for-enhanced-climate-action/
BF4266550F09E5E4A7479E09C047B984
305 Böhringer, C., Carbone, J.C., & Rutherford, T. F.
(2018). Embodied Carbon Tariffs. The Scandinavian Journal
of Economics, 120(1), 183–210. Retrieved from https://
onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/abs/10.1111/sjoe.12211
306 Rounsevell M. D. A. et al. (2020). A biodiversity
target based on species extinctions. Science,368(6496),
1193-1195. Retrieved from https://science.sciencemag.org/
content/368/6496/1193.summary
307 Trachtman, J. P. (2017). WTO Law Constraints on
Border Tax Adjustment and Tax Credit Mechanisms to
Reduce the Competitive Effects of Carbon Taxes. National
Tax Journal 70(2), 469–93. Retrieved from https://ideas.
repec.org/a/ntj/journl/v70y2017i2p469-494.html
308 Zachmann, G., & McWilliams, B. (2020). A European
Carbon Border Tax: Much Pain, Little Gain (Issue nr°2).
Brussels: Bruegel.
309 Kortum, S., & Weisbach, D. (2017). The Design of
Border Adjustments for Carbon Prices. National Tax Journal
70(2), 421–446. Retrieved from https://ideas.repec.org/a/
ntj/journl/v70y2017i2p421-446.html
310 Zachmann, G., & McWilliams, B. (2020). A European
Carbon Border Tax: Much Pain, Little Gain (Issue nr°2).
Brussels: Bruegel.
311 Weitzel, M., Hübler, M., & Peterson, S. (2012). Fair,
Optimal or Detrimental? Environmental vs. Strategic Use of
Border Carbon Adjustment. Energy Economics, 34, 198–207.
Retrieved from https://www.researchgate.net/publica-
tion/256967832_Fair_Optimal_or_Detrimental_Environ-
mental_vs_strategic_use_of_border_carbon_adjustment
312 Davidson Ladley, S. (2012). Border Carbon
Adjustments, WTO-Law and the Principle of Common but
Differentiated Responsibilities. International Environmental
Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics 12(1), 63–84.
Retrieved from https://ideas.repec.org/a/spr/ieaple/
v12y2012i1p63-84.html
Title Authors
Pub -
lished
Key Questions
Theories, Models,
Methods
Recommendations
Useful Insights and
Arguments
Financing the transition – how
nancial system Reform can
serve sustainable development
Nick Robins, Jeremy
McDaniels
2016 What measures are most needed to deliver
efciency, effectiveness and resilience in
ways that the nancial system can contribute
to specic sustainability priorities in the real
economy?
Case studies
on sustainable
energy, climate risk
assessment and
sustainable land
use; Geographies:
India, EU, France,
Netherlands,
Sweden, UK,
California, Brazil,
Indonesia
Repurpose subsidized credit to comply with environmental
indicators (e. g. no deforestation in Brazil). Improve
disclosure, data and risk analytics (e. g. for energy
efciency). Integrate nancial sector considerations into
sectoral environmental policy. Think in system terms to
identify key drivers of change in nance.
System thinking approach of the
study.
Delivering the sustainable
nancial system the world
needs
Steve Waygood and
others
2017 How can private nance be aligned with the
Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs)?
SDGs or sustainability aligned benchmark. Guidance on
duciary duty to include non-nancial objectives. Financial
education to build demand for long-term products.
Doughnut economics: seven
ways to think like a 21st
century economist
Raworth, Kate 2017 How can we frame an economy that
integrates social wellbeing into planetary
boundaries within the “safe and just operating
space for humanity”?
Doughnut frame-
work, planetary
boundaries
Seven steps to think like a 21st century economist:
1. Change the goal
2. Tell a new story
3. Nurture human nature
4. Get savvy with systems
5. Design to distribute
6. Create to regenerate
7. Be agnostic about growth
Economics as a sphere in which
people produce, distribute and
consume products and services
that satisfy their wishes and
needs. Distinguishes between
four supply spheres: individual
household, market, commons,
state. Economy is not a closed
cycle, but an open system with
constant inflows and outflows of
raw materials and energy. The
most important resource flow is
not money, but the energy cycle.
The IPBES Global Assessment
report – Summary for
policymakers of the global
assessment report on biodi-
versity and ecosystem services
of the Intergovernmental
Science-Policy Platform on
Biodiversity and Ecosystem
Services.
IPBES – Díaz, J. Settele,
E. S. Brondízio E.S., H. T.
Ngo, M. Guèze, J. Agard,
A. Arneth, P. Balvanera,
K. A. Brauman, S. H. M.
Butchart, K. M. A. Chan,
L. A. Garibaldi, K. Ichii, J.
Liu, S. M. Subramanian,
G. F. Midgley, P. Miloslav-
ich, Z. Molnár, D. Obura,
A. Pfaff, S. Polasky, A.
Purvis, J. Razzaque,
B. Reyers, R. Roy
Chowdhury, Y. J. Shin, I.
J. Visseren-Hamakers, K.
J. Willis, and C. N. Zayas
(eds.). IPBES secretariat,
Bonn, Germany. 56
pages.
2019 Status, trends and drivers of change in nature
for better evidence-informed policy decisions
and action at the local, national, regional and
global levels.
State-of-the-art
literature review.
Revolves on a
conceptual model
which represents
the links between
nature and human
wellbeing (as
well as drivers,
institutions, and
other elements).
Scenario-based
modelling is used in
one specic Chapter
(Ch. 4).
Reforming subsidies
Address over and under consumption
Reducing unsustainable production
Reforming trade regimes and nancial systems
Reforming models of economic growth
Acknowledging nature’s
contributions to people’s life to
consider environmental impacts
in economic decision-making.
Biodiversity loss means loss of
wellbeing, including economic
welfare.
Content
102
Appendix
Title Authors
Pub -
lished
Key Questions
Theories, Models,
Methods
Recommendations
Useful Insights and
Arguments
Financing the transition – how
nancial system Reform can
serve sustainable development
Nick Robins, Jeremy
McDaniels
2016 What measures are most needed to deliver
efciency, effectiveness and resilience in
ways that the nancial system can contribute
to specic sustainability priorities in the real
economy?
Case studies
on sustainable
energy, climate risk
assessment and
sustainable land
use; Geographies:
India, EU, France,
Netherlands,
Sweden, UK,
California, Brazil,
Indonesia
Repurpose subsidized credit to comply with environmental
indicators (e. g. no deforestation in Brazil). Improve
disclosure, data and risk analytics (e. g. for energy
efciency). Integrate nancial sector considerations into
sectoral environmental policy. Think in system terms to
identify key drivers of change in nance.
System thinking approach of the
study.
Delivering the sustainable
nancial system the world
needs
Steve Waygood and
others
2017 How can private nance be aligned with the
Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs)?
SDGs or sustainability aligned benchmark. Guidance on
duciary duty to include non-nancial objectives. Financial
education to build demand for long-term products.
Doughnut economics: seven
ways to think like a 21st
century economist
Raworth, Kate 2017 How can we frame an economy that
integrates social wellbeing into planetary
boundaries within the “safe and just operating
space for humanity”?
Doughnut frame-
work, planetary
boundaries
Seven steps to think like a 21st century economist:
1. Change the goal
2. Tell a new story
3. Nurture human nature
4. Get savvy with systems
5. Design to distribute
6. Create to regenerate
7. Be agnostic about growth
Economics as a sphere in which
people produce, distribute and
consume products and services
that satisfy their wishes and
needs. Distinguishes between
four supply spheres: individual
household, market, commons,
state. Economy is not a closed
cycle, but an open system with
constant inflows and outflows of
raw materials and energy. The
most important resource flow is
not money, but the energy cycle.
The IPBES Global Assessment
report – Summary for
policymakers of the global
assessment report on biodi-
versity and ecosystem services
of the Intergovernmental
Science-Policy Platform on
Biodiversity and Ecosystem
Services.
IPBES – Díaz, J. Settele,
E. S. Brondízio E.S., H. T.
Ngo, M. Guèze, J. Agard,
A. Arneth, P. Balvanera,
K. A. Brauman, S. H. M.
Butchart, K. M. A. Chan,
L. A. Garibaldi, K. Ichii, J.
Liu, S. M. Subramanian,
G. F. Midgley, P. Miloslav-
ich, Z. Molnár, D. Obura,
A. Pfaff, S. Polasky, A.
Purvis, J. Razzaque,
B. Reyers, R. Roy
Chowdhury, Y. J. Shin, I.
J. Visseren-Hamakers, K.
J. Willis, and C. N. Zayas
(eds.). IPBES secretariat,
Bonn, Germany. 56
pages.
2019 Status, trends and drivers of change in nature
for better evidence-informed policy decisions
and action at the local, national, regional and
global levels.
State-of-the-art
literature review.
Revolves on a
conceptual model
which represents
the links between
nature and human
wellbeing (as
well as drivers,
institutions, and
other elements).
Scenario-based
modelling is used in
one specic Chapter
(Ch. 4).
Reforming subsidies
Address over and under consumption
Reducing unsustainable production
Reforming trade regimes and nancial systems
Reforming models of economic growth
Acknowledging nature’s
contributions to people’s life to
consider environmental impacts
in economic decision-making.
Biodiversity loss means loss of
wellbeing, including economic
welfare.
103
Content
Title Authors
Pub -
lished
Key Questions
Theories, Models,
Methods
Recommendations
Useful Insights and
Arguments
Assessing the degrowth
discourse: A review and
analysis of academic degrowth
policy proposals
Cosme, Inês, Rui Santos,
und Daniel W. O’Neill
2017 Which areas of impact are covered by
degrowth policy proposals and where are its
underdeveloped parts/blind spots?
Literature review of
128 peer-reviewed
papers and 54 that
include proposals
for action.
Meta-study, analyzing policy proposals concerning three
goals: 1) Reduce the environmental impact of human
activities. 2) Redistribute income and wealth both within
and between countries. 3) Promote the transition from a
materialistic to a convivial and participatory society.
Degrowth – Vocabulary for a
new era
Giacomo D´Alisa
Federico Demaria
Giorgos Kallis
2015 What are the different strands of critique and
proposals of the degrowth community?
Recommendation for a transition to a degrowth economy,
that goes along with new allocations between private and
public provisioning of goods and services, a stricter focus
on environmental limits, a different concept of wellbeing
and more equality.
New understanding of wellbeing,
that is less based on personal
gain and more on redistribution,
because evidence has shown,
that above a certain level of
national income, it is equality and
not growth that improves social
wellbeing (Wilkinson and Pickett
2009).
Climate and nature and our
1.5° future – WWF synthesis of
the IPBES and IPCC reports
Stephen Cornelius
Sophie Yeo
Christopher Weber,
Fernanda Carvalho,
Leanne Clare, Mandy
Woods, Pauli Merriman,
Roz Pidcock, Vanessa
Perez-Cirera
2019 What are the systemic changes needed
for limiting global warming and halting
biodiversity loss?
Synthesis review
of IPCC and IPBES
reports structured
by ecosystem
type. Case studies
and specic WWF
recommendations
based on the
reports.
Climate pledges consistent with the 1.5°C goal. Nature-
based solutions part of countries’ climate commitments.
Coordinate climate, biodiversity and sustainable
development policies. Align nancial flows with the needed
systems transformations. Address the international
impacts of domestic policies.
Nature-based solutions, sustain-
able consumption and production
can be synergically used to tackle
climate change and biodiversity
loss.
Mobilising Private Sector
Capital in Support of the UN
Sustainable Development
Goals
UNDP, Global Ethical
Finance Initative, R.J.
Fleming & Co
2020 How to incentivise the investment sector to
support the UN SDGs?
Survey and
interviews with over
100+ senior reps
from investment
space
SDGs
Products: BONDS (e. g. Sustainable Bonds: Green Bond,
Green Sukuk, Green Securitisation Bond, Blue Bond,
Sustainability Linked Bond, Social Bond, Forests Bond]
Impact Funds, Blended Finance, Green Loan, Sustainability
Linked-Loan)
Challenges in integrating –
(1) Risk & Return, (2) Scale,
(3) Ratings – ESG rating are
inherently subjective and
investors have to undertake
own analysis of sustainability
factors – (4) Measuring &
Reporting – several initiatives
without standard or widespread
adoption (5), Liquidity-lacking
due to supply/demand imbalance
(6), Government support
– policy is critical to shaping
investment climate in markets,
(7) Greenwashing.
The Business of Wellbeing
Mira Bangel and Michael
Weatherhead
2020 How can businesses participate in a wellbeing
economy?
Co-created guide
with SenseTribe
w/interviews
with partners and
stakeholders
Businesses want to participate
in a wellbeing economy, but
competition prevents it.
Creating incentives for sharing
innovations to enable other
businesses is key.
Using TCFDs to manage
climate risk: next steps for UK
government, investors and
businesses
Aldersgate Group 2019 How can the nancial sector address climate
risk?
1. Reporting of climate change risk should be mandatory
to provide data and create a level playing eld
2. Governments should require companies to disclose
what actions they’re taking to manage identied risk
3. Market participants must be encouraged to look beyond
usual business planning timelines
4. Corporate Reporting Lab should be established to
develop impartial sectoral scenario guidance companies
in same industries
5. UK must keep up with international trends on climate
disclosure
6. Investors must make voice heard and engage with
companies
Establish a leveled playing eld,
introduce Mandatory reporting,
corporate Reporting Lab should
be set-up, go beyond “BAU”
timelines and more forward
thinking.
Content
104
Title Authors
Pub -
lished
Key Questions
Theories, Models,
Methods
Recommendations
Useful Insights and
Arguments
Assessing the degrowth
discourse: A review and
analysis of academic degrowth
policy proposals
Cosme, Inês, Rui Santos,
und Daniel W. O’Neill
2017 Which areas of impact are covered by
degrowth policy proposals and where are its
underdeveloped parts/blind spots?
Literature review of
128 peer-reviewed
papers and 54 that
include proposals
for action.
Meta-study, analyzing policy proposals concerning three
goals: 1) Reduce the environmental impact of human
activities. 2) Redistribute income and wealth both within
and between countries. 3) Promote the transition from a
materialistic to a convivial and participatory society.
Degrowth – Vocabulary for a
new era
Giacomo D´Alisa
Federico Demaria
Giorgos Kallis
2015 What are the different strands of critique and
proposals of the degrowth community?
Recommendation for a transition to a degrowth economy,
that goes along with new allocations between private and
public provisioning of goods and services, a stricter focus
on environmental limits, a different concept of wellbeing
and more equality.
New understanding of wellbeing,
that is less based on personal
gain and more on redistribution,
because evidence has shown,
that above a certain level of
national income, it is equality and
not growth that improves social
wellbeing (Wilkinson and Pickett
2009).
Climate and nature and our
1.5° future – WWF synthesis of
the IPBES and IPCC reports
Stephen Cornelius
Sophie Yeo
Christopher Weber,
Fernanda Carvalho,
Leanne Clare, Mandy
Woods, Pauli Merriman,
Roz Pidcock, Vanessa
Perez-Cirera
2019 What are the systemic changes needed
for limiting global warming and halting
biodiversity loss?
Synthesis review
of IPCC and IPBES
reports structured
by ecosystem
type. Case studies
and specic WWF
recommendations
based on the
reports.
Climate pledges consistent with the 1.5°C goal. Nature-
based solutions part of countries’ climate commitments.
Coordinate climate, biodiversity and sustainable
development policies. Align nancial flows with the needed
systems transformations. Address the international
impacts of domestic policies.
Nature-based solutions, sustain-
able consumption and production
can be synergically used to tackle
climate change and biodiversity
loss.
Mobilising Private Sector
Capital in Support of the UN
Sustainable Development
Goals
UNDP, Global Ethical
Finance Initative, R.J.
Fleming & Co
2020 How to incentivise the investment sector to
support the UN SDGs?
Survey and
interviews with over
100+ senior reps
from investment
space
SDGs
Products: BONDS (e. g. Sustainable Bonds: Green Bond,
Green Sukuk, Green Securitisation Bond, Blue Bond,
Sustainability Linked Bond, Social Bond, Forests Bond]
Impact Funds, Blended Finance, Green Loan, Sustainability
Linked-Loan)
Challenges in integrating –
(1) Risk & Return, (2) Scale,
(3) Ratings – ESG rating are
inherently subjective and
investors have to undertake
own analysis of sustainability
factors – (4) Measuring &
Reporting – several initiatives
without standard or widespread
adoption (5), Liquidity-lacking
due to supply/demand imbalance
(6), Government support
– policy is critical to shaping
investment climate in markets,
(7) Greenwashing.
The Business of Wellbeing
Mira Bangel and Michael
Weatherhead
2020 How can businesses participate in a wellbeing
economy?
Co-created guide
with SenseTribe
w/interviews
with partners and
stakeholders
Businesses want to participate
in a wellbeing economy, but
competition prevents it.
Creating incentives for sharing
innovations to enable other
businesses is key.
Using TCFDs to manage
climate risk: next steps for UK
government, investors and
businesses
Aldersgate Group 2019 How can the nancial sector address climate
risk?
1. Reporting of climate change risk should be mandatory
to provide data and create a level playing eld
2. Governments should require companies to disclose
what actions they’re taking to manage identied risk
3. Market participants must be encouraged to look beyond
usual business planning timelines
4. Corporate Reporting Lab should be established to
develop impartial sectoral scenario guidance companies
in same industries
5. UK must keep up with international trends on climate
disclosure
6. Investors must make voice heard and engage with
companies
Establish a leveled playing eld,
introduce Mandatory reporting,
corporate Reporting Lab should
be set-up, go beyond “BAU”
timelines and more forward
thinking.
105
Content
Title Authors
Pub -
lished
Key Questions
Theories, Models,
Methods
Recommendations
Useful Insights and
Arguments
2019 Global Sustainable
Development Report
Independent Group of
Scientists appointed
by the UN Secre-
tary-General: Co-chairs;
Peter Messerli, Endah
Murniningtyas
2019 Current shortfall of Sustainable Development
Goals by 2030
SDGs and
assessment of SDG
achievements.
Put inequality at heart of global development agenda.
Promote agreement, inclusivity and consensus to achieve
policies that work for the common good, rather than
narrow self-interest, across both the public and the private
sectors.
Emphasis on the role of science
for designing and implementing
development policies (systems
approach).
UNISDR (2017) Build Back
Better in recovery, rehabilita-
tion and reconstruction.
(Consultative version)
UNISDR 2017 Best practices for disaster recovery across
countries?
Building of a
common framework
through identifying
common termi-
nology, agreeing
on priorities and
learning from best
practices.
Strengthen policies, laws, programs that promote
(incentivise), guide (ensure), and support Build Back Better
in recovery, rehabilitation, and reconstruction in public and
private sectors, and by individuals and households.
Learning from best practices
across the world offers solutions
for global-scale challenges.
The Tragedy of Growth
Positive Money 2020 How can the UK government move past GDP
measurement toward measurements of
wellbeing?
Abandon GDP as a indicator of progress
Transition to a non-nancialised and non-growing system
Incorporate a dashboard of social and environmental
wellbeing indicators into the policy process
Foster balanced creditor – debtor
relationships – founded on ways
of guaranteeing access to means
of payment and access to credit
UBI issues via central bank
currency, direct clearing facility,
banks and modern debt jubilees
as policy.
Natures Return: Embedding
environmental goals at the
heart of economic and nancial
decision-making
Ludovic Suttor Sorel and
Nicolas Hercellin
2020 1. Is private nance up to the task [nancing
the preservation of biodiversity]?
2. Are current regulatory proposals able to
scale up the mobilization of nance for
nature?
3. If not, what interventions can bring deep
and lasting changes to the provision of
nance for nature?
Exploration of
(neoclassical)
Modern Portfolio
Theory and the
Capital Assets
Pricing Model
to illustrate the
inadequateness of
the current nancial
system to nance
environmental
projects.
Update the metrics for tracking environmental impact
from the Rio Markers to the BioFin ones [in EU].
End counterproductive agricultural subsidies and redi-
rect them for transitioning to nature preserving practices
Exempt public investments in nature from public decit
rules as they can be counted as capital investments
Better enforce environmental regulations
Explore blending of public and private nancing for a
limited number of areas
Counters the nancial innovation
arguments.
Towards a performance
framework for a sustainable
nancial system
Wally Turbeville 2016 Exploring the connection between available
liquidity and fulllment of investment flows
for sustainability (and the need to divert
from unsustainable activities) to assess the
functionality of the nancial system and come
up with recommendations for reform.
Revisits Mynski’s
Financial Instability
Hypothesis, the
Efcient Market
Hypothesis and the
work on the cost of
intermediation from
Phillipon and the
Bank for Interna-
tional Settlements.
Assess the nancial system not by self-referential metrics
like amount of transactions or liquidity of the market but in
terms of its system outputs, i.e. whether or not it delivers
the investments that are needed for the transition towards
a sustainable economy.
Framework to conceptualise
nance as a system as well as
meaningful categories to assess
its functionality.
COVID-19: the future of UK
economic policy
Giles Wilkes; Kiran
Horwich
2020 Examining the big policy questions that lie
ahead (through COVID-19), and how they
might develop through four key phases of
action.
Measuring Prosperity –
Navigating the options
Christine Corlet Walker;
Tim Jackson
2019 How can we move beyond GDP in measuring
prosperity?
1. discusses the benets and disadvantages
of the different types of alternative
indicators
2. contribute to challenge of aggregation and
the question of monetization
3. a roadmap for interested parties to better
understand what makes a successful and
influential indicator
The “story indicator” must be clear and distinct from the
story captured by GDP. It can benet from simplicity and
aggregation, allowing them to compete with GDP on the
public stage. The “decision-aid indicatorrequires closer
attention to technical characteristics as well as inclusion of
end-users and political context.
Content
106
Title Authors
Pub -
lished
Key Questions
Theories, Models,
Methods
Recommendations
Useful Insights and
Arguments
2019 Global Sustainable
Development Report
Independent Group of
Scientists appointed
by the UN Secre-
tary-General: Co-chairs;
Peter Messerli, Endah
Murniningtyas
2019 Current shortfall of Sustainable Development
Goals by 2030
SDGs and
assessment of SDG
achievements.
Put inequality at heart of global development agenda.
Promote agreement, inclusivity and consensus to achieve
policies that work for the common good, rather than
narrow self-interest, across both the public and the private
sectors.
Emphasis on the role of science
for designing and implementing
development policies (systems
approach).
UNISDR (2017) Build Back
Better in recovery, rehabilita-
tion and reconstruction.
(Consultative version)
UNISDR 2017 Best practices for disaster recovery across
countries?
Building of a
common framework
through identifying
common termi-
nology, agreeing
on priorities and
learning from best
practices.
Strengthen policies, laws, programs that promote
(incentivise), guide (ensure), and support Build Back Better
in recovery, rehabilitation, and reconstruction in public and
private sectors, and by individuals and households.
Learning from best practices
across the world offers solutions
for global-scale challenges.
The Tragedy of Growth
Positive Money 2020 How can the UK government move past GDP
measurement toward measurements of
wellbeing?
Abandon GDP as a indicator of progress
Transition to a non-nancialised and non-growing system
Incorporate a dashboard of social and environmental
wellbeing indicators into the policy process
Foster balanced creditor – debtor
relationships – founded on ways
of guaranteeing access to means
of payment and access to credit
UBI issues via central bank
currency, direct clearing facility,
banks and modern debt jubilees
as policy.
Natures Return: Embedding
environmental goals at the
heart of economic and nancial
decision-making
Ludovic Suttor Sorel and
Nicolas Hercellin
2020 1. Is private nance up to the task [nancing
the preservation of biodiversity]?
2. Are current regulatory proposals able to
scale up the mobilization of nance for
nature?
3. If not, what interventions can bring deep
and lasting changes to the provision of
nance for nature?
Exploration of
(neoclassical)
Modern Portfolio
Theory and the
Capital Assets
Pricing Model
to illustrate the
inadequateness of
the current nancial
system to nance
environmental
projects.
Update the metrics for tracking environmental impact
from the Rio Markers to the BioFin ones [in EU].
End counterproductive agricultural subsidies and redi-
rect them for transitioning to nature preserving practices
Exempt public investments in nature from public decit
rules as they can be counted as capital investments
Better enforce environmental regulations
Explore blending of public and private nancing for a
limited number of areas
Counters the nancial innovation
arguments.
Towards a performance
framework for a sustainable
nancial system
Wally Turbeville 2016 Exploring the connection between available
liquidity and fulllment of investment flows
for sustainability (and the need to divert
from unsustainable activities) to assess the
functionality of the nancial system and come
up with recommendations for reform.
Revisits Mynski’s
Financial Instability
Hypothesis, the
Efcient Market
Hypothesis and the
work on the cost of
intermediation from
Phillipon and the
Bank for Interna-
tional Settlements.
Assess the nancial system not by self-referential metrics
like amount of transactions or liquidity of the market but in
terms of its system outputs, i.e. whether or not it delivers
the investments that are needed for the transition towards
a sustainable economy.
Framework to conceptualise
nance as a system as well as
meaningful categories to assess
its functionality.
COVID-19: the future of UK
economic policy
Giles Wilkes; Kiran
Horwich
2020 Examining the big policy questions that lie
ahead (through COVID-19), and how they
might develop through four key phases of
action.
Measuring Prosperity –
Navigating the options
Christine Corlet Walker;
Tim Jackson
2019 How can we move beyond GDP in measuring
prosperity?
1. discusses the benets and disadvantages
of the different types of alternative
indicators
2. contribute to challenge of aggregation and
the question of monetization
3. a roadmap for interested parties to better
understand what makes a successful and
influential indicator
The “story indicator” must be clear and distinct from the
story captured by GDP. It can benet from simplicity and
aggregation, allowing them to compete with GDP on the
public stage. The “decision-aid indicatorrequires closer
attention to technical characteristics as well as inclusion of
end-users and political context.
107
Content
Title Authors
Pub -
lished
Key Questions
Theories, Models,
Methods
Recommendations
Useful Insights and
Arguments
From containment to recovery:
Environmental responses to
the COVID-19 pandemic
OECD 2020 Focus on immediate steps that governments
can take to ensure COVID-19 emergency
measures do not derail efforts to address
environmental challenges and improve envi-
ronmental health and resilience of societies.
The regulatory compass
towards a purpose-driven
approach to nancial
regulation – Finance
Innovation Lab
Christine Berry, Anna
Laycock, Rob Nash and
Marloes Nichols
2018 What is the purpose of nance and how can
reforms make the nancial system closer to
deliver on this purpose?
Case studies Update metrics for performance assessments
Reform the mandates of regulators and change the
mindsets of people involved in nance
Blueprint for Better business
Blueprint for Better
Business
2019 What is a purpose driven business?
1. Honest and Fair with Customers and Suppliers
2. A Good Citizen- seeing each person affected by
decisions as if they were a member of the decision-
makers own community
3. A Responsible and Responsive Employer – treats
everyone with dignity and provides fair pay
4. A Guardian for Future Generations
Framework on how businesses
can do more for employees and
community as a whole.
Will COVID-19 Fiscal recovery
packages accelerate or retard
progress on climate change?
Cameron Hepburn, Brian
O’Callahjan, Nicholas
Stern, Joseph Sitglitz,
Dimitri Zenghelis
2020 Will COVID-19 Fiscal recovery packages
accelerate or retard progress on climate
change?
Policies can deliver both economic and climate goals,
co-benets can be captured, prioritise policy design
Green scal recovery packages
can act to decouple economic
growth from GHG emissions and
reduce existing welfare inequal-
ities that will be exacerbated by
the pandemic in the short-term
and climate change in the
long-term.
Successful non-growing
companies
Andrea Liesen, Christian
Dietsche, Jana Gebauer
2014 Who are the successful non-growing
companies and what is their potential in a
post-growth economy?
Document analysis
(i. e. systematic
procedure that
entails nding,
selecting, apprais-
ing (making sense
of), and synthesis-
ing data contained
in documents”
Produce not cheaper and more, but less and more
valuable products
Spare resources by reducing output
Increase the immaterial benet of the printing process
e. g. experience quality, focusing on useful printing
products
Distribute prots and provide reasonable compensation
for all employees
Identify indicators that allow to more easily measure and
communicate success of non-growing companies
Aim for better not bigger
Focus on quality of products/
services and quality of work
and life
Make contribution to reduce
absolute amount of resource
use
Global Futures: Modelling
the global economic impacts
of environmental change to
support policy-making (WWF
report)
Justin Andrew Jackson,
Uris Lantz Baldos,
Thomas Hertel, Chirs
Nootenboom, Stephen
Polasky, Toby Roxburgh
2020 What is the impact of different scenarios
concerning the (non)-preservation of ecosys-
tems on GDP by the year 2050?
Ecosystem model
is pegged onto
computable general
equilibrium model
through input-out-
put accounts,
where inputs are
shocked due to the
deterioration of the
environment. The
integrated model
uses representative
agendas, discount-
ing, and GDP growth
trajectories that
are obtained from
historical trends
and carbon prices
from Integrated
Assessment Models
Shift to sustainable economic practices and restoration of
land leads to less adverse economic effects, while being
able to maintain food for the world populations. Hence,
policy and behavioural shifts that comply with a conserva-
tion scenario should be undertaken.
Estimates on the monetary
losses from the destruction
of ecosystem services like
pollination or coastal
ecosystems.
Content
108
Title Authors
Pub -
lished
Key Questions
Theories, Models,
Methods
Recommendations
Useful Insights and
Arguments
From containment to recovery:
Environmental responses to
the COVID-19 pandemic
OECD 2020 Focus on immediate steps that governments
can take to ensure COVID-19 emergency
measures do not derail efforts to address
environmental challenges and improve envi-
ronmental health and resilience of societies.
The regulatory compass
towards a purpose-driven
approach to nancial
regulation – Finance
Innovation Lab
Christine Berry, Anna
Laycock, Rob Nash and
Marloes Nichols
2018 What is the purpose of nance and how can
reforms make the nancial system closer to
deliver on this purpose?
Case studies Update metrics for performance assessments
Reform the mandates of regulators and change the
mindsets of people involved in nance
Blueprint for Better business
Blueprint for Better
Business
2019 What is a purpose driven business?
1. Honest and Fair with Customers and Suppliers
2. A Good Citizen- seeing each person affected by
decisions as if they were a member of the decision-
makers own community
3. A Responsible and Responsive Employer – treats
everyone with dignity and provides fair pay
4. A Guardian for Future Generations
Framework on how businesses
can do more for employees and
community as a whole.
Will COVID-19 Fiscal recovery
packages accelerate or retard
progress on climate change?
Cameron Hepburn, Brian
O’Callahjan, Nicholas
Stern, Joseph Sitglitz,
Dimitri Zenghelis
2020 Will COVID-19 Fiscal recovery packages
accelerate or retard progress on climate
change?
Policies can deliver both economic and climate goals,
co-benets can be captured, prioritise policy design
Green scal recovery packages
can act to decouple economic
growth from GHG emissions and
reduce existing welfare inequal-
ities that will be exacerbated by
the pandemic in the short-term
and climate change in the
long-term.
Successful non-growing
companies
Andrea Liesen, Christian
Dietsche, Jana Gebauer
2014 Who are the successful non-growing
companies and what is their potential in a
post-growth economy?
Document analysis
(i. e. systematic
procedure that
entails nding,
selecting, apprais-
ing (making sense
of), and synthesis-
ing data contained
in documents”
Produce not cheaper and more, but less and more
valuable products
Spare resources by reducing output
Increase the immaterial benet of the printing process
e. g. experience quality, focusing on useful printing
products
Distribute prots and provide reasonable compensation
for all employees
Identify indicators that allow to more easily measure and
communicate success of non-growing companies
Aim for better not bigger
Focus on quality of products/
services and quality of work
and life
Make contribution to reduce
absolute amount of resource
use
Global Futures: Modelling
the global economic impacts
of environmental change to
support policy-making (WWF
report)
Justin Andrew Jackson,
Uris Lantz Baldos,
Thomas Hertel, Chirs
Nootenboom, Stephen
Polasky, Toby Roxburgh
2020 What is the impact of different scenarios
concerning the (non)-preservation of ecosys-
tems on GDP by the year 2050?
Ecosystem model
is pegged onto
computable general
equilibrium model
through input-out-
put accounts,
where inputs are
shocked due to the
deterioration of the
environment. The
integrated model
uses representative
agendas, discount-
ing, and GDP growth
trajectories that
are obtained from
historical trends
and carbon prices
from Integrated
Assessment Models
Shift to sustainable economic practices and restoration of
land leads to less adverse economic effects, while being
able to maintain food for the world populations. Hence,
policy and behavioural shifts that comply with a conserva-
tion scenario should be undertaken.
Estimates on the monetary
losses from the destruction
of ecosystem services like
pollination or coastal
ecosystems.
109
Content
Title Authors
Pub -
lished
Key Questions
Theories, Models,
Methods
Recommendations
Useful Insights and
Arguments
Growth, Degrowth and Climate
Change: A scenario Analysis
Peter A. Victor 2011 What are the various scenarios of economic
growth that impact GHG emissions?
Many models
comparing BAU,
low/no growth
scenarios against
one another
Low/no growth economy scenario to see how it can affect
GHG emissions, government spending, carbon tax, working
time, population, poverty, unemployment, and debt.
As GDP rises, so does debt, GHG
emissions and poverty. In low/no
growth scenario, GHG reduces,
unemployment, debt and poverty
all reduce.
Wellbeing Economics for the
COVID-19 Recovery
Milena Büchs, Marta
Baltruszewicz, Katharina
Bohnenberger, Jonathan
Busch, James Dyke,
Patrick Elf, Andrew
Fanning, Martin Fritz,
Alice Garvey, Lukas
Hardt, Elena Hofferberth,
Diana Ivanova, Amanda
Janoo, Dan O’Neill,
Monica Guillen-Royo,
Marlyne Sahakian, Julia
Steinberger, Katherine
Trebeck, Christine Corlet
Walker
2020 How can governments build back better
toward economies focused on wellbeing?
Policies for building
back better are
contrasted with
building back worse
policies.
Doughnut economics framework in Amsterdam
Wellbeing Economy Government partnership
Green Deal
Pop-up bike lanes
Green recovery plans
Sharing partnerships
Basic incomes
Freezing debt payments for low income countries
Put dividend and bonus payments on hold (banks and
coops)
Quantitative Easing measures or direct public money
creation
Best practice examples.
Recommendations in the
IPCC special reports on global
warming of 1.5 ºC, land, the
ocean and cryosphere
IPCC 2018 What are the impacts of impacts of global
warming of 1.5°C above pre-industrial levels?
Scenarios Avoiding carbon overshoot can only be achieved if global
CO2 emissions start to decline well before 2030
A wide range of adaptation options should be used to
reduce the risks related to global warming
Mitigation strategies to reduce net carbon emissions are
required to avoid more severe impacts.
Limiting global warming to 1.5°C
requires rapid and far-reaching
transitions in energy, land, urban
and infrastructure (including
transport and buildings), and
industrial systems. Climate
change generates negative
impacts on sustainable develop-
ment, eradication of poverty and
reducing inequalities.
Come On! Capitalism, Short-
termism, Population and the
Destruction of the Planet
von Weizsäcker and
Wijkman
2017 How to create more resilient economies
and why our current economic systems is
insufcient?
SDGs, planetary
boundaries, regen-
erative principles
– Fullerton, blue
economy etc.
Rethink taxation
Strengthen recycling and reuse targets
Strengthen existing policies of promoting renewable
energy
Introduce design requirements for new products for ease
of repair and maintenance
Use public procurement to incentivise new business
models
Make material efciency a core part of climate mitigation
policies.
Launch investments, primarily in infrastructure, to
support the circular economy
Support innovation in low-carbon solutions
Exempt all secondary materials from VAT
Climate Change: An Antidote
To Democracys Mid-life Crisis
Richard Roberts 2018 How to make climate policy that is effective?
1. A flatrate, no-exceptions tax on emissions.
2. Investment in renewables and low-emission transport
infrastructure, which will also create jobs.
3. Enhanced protections for natural carbon sinks in public
hands.
4. Funding for research into carbon capture and use,
energy storage and next generation renewables.
5. Higher mandatory energy efciency standards for all
new buildings.
6. Scrappage schemes
7. Investment in climate adaptation and resilience.
8. Public awareness campaigns to promote dietary
changes that both reduce emissions and improve
health.
9. Lowering the voting age to 16.
Content
110
Title Authors
Pub -
lished
Key Questions
Theories, Models,
Methods
Recommendations
Useful Insights and
Arguments
Growth, Degrowth and Climate
Change: A scenario Analysis
Peter A. Victor 2011 What are the various scenarios of economic
growth that impact GHG emissions?
Many models
comparing BAU,
low/no growth
scenarios against
one another
Low/no growth economy scenario to see how it can affect
GHG emissions, government spending, carbon tax, working
time, population, poverty, unemployment, and debt.
As GDP rises, so does debt, GHG
emissions and poverty. In low/no
growth scenario, GHG reduces,
unemployment, debt and poverty
all reduce.
Wellbeing Economics for the
COVID-19 Recovery
Milena Büchs, Marta
Baltruszewicz, Katharina
Bohnenberger, Jonathan
Busch, James Dyke,
Patrick Elf, Andrew
Fanning, Martin Fritz,
Alice Garvey, Lukas
Hardt, Elena Hofferberth,
Diana Ivanova, Amanda
Janoo, Dan O’Neill,
Monica Guillen-Royo,
Marlyne Sahakian, Julia
Steinberger, Katherine
Trebeck, Christine Corlet
Walker
2020 How can governments build back better
toward economies focused on wellbeing?
Policies for building
back better are
contrasted with
building back worse
policies.
Doughnut economics framework in Amsterdam
Wellbeing Economy Government partnership
Green Deal
Pop-up bike lanes
Green recovery plans
Sharing partnerships
Basic incomes
Freezing debt payments for low income countries
Put dividend and bonus payments on hold (banks and
coops)
Quantitative Easing measures or direct public money
creation
Best practice examples.
Recommendations in the
IPCC special reports on global
warming of 1.5 ºC, land, the
ocean and cryosphere
IPCC 2018 What are the impacts of impacts of global
warming of 1.5°C above pre-industrial levels?
Scenarios Avoiding carbon overshoot can only be achieved if global
CO2 emissions start to decline well before 2030
A wide range of adaptation options should be used to
reduce the risks related to global warming
Mitigation strategies to reduce net carbon emissions are
required to avoid more severe impacts.
Limiting global warming to 1.5°C
requires rapid and far-reaching
transitions in energy, land, urban
and infrastructure (including
transport and buildings), and
industrial systems. Climate
change generates negative
impacts on sustainable develop-
ment, eradication of poverty and
reducing inequalities.
Come On! Capitalism, Short-
termism, Population and the
Destruction of the Planet
von Weizsäcker and
Wijkman
2017 How to create more resilient economies
and why our current economic systems is
insufcient?
SDGs, planetary
boundaries, regen-
erative principles
– Fullerton, blue
economy etc.
Rethink taxation
Strengthen recycling and reuse targets
Strengthen existing policies of promoting renewable
energy
Introduce design requirements for new products for ease
of repair and maintenance
Use public procurement to incentivise new business
models
Make material efciency a core part of climate mitigation
policies.
Launch investments, primarily in infrastructure, to
support the circular economy
Support innovation in low-carbon solutions
Exempt all secondary materials from VAT
Climate Change: An Antidote
To Democracys Mid-life Crisis
Richard Roberts 2018 How to make climate policy that is effective?
1. A flatrate, no-exceptions tax on emissions.
2. Investment in renewables and low-emission transport
infrastructure, which will also create jobs.
3. Enhanced protections for natural carbon sinks in public
hands.
4. Funding for research into carbon capture and use,
energy storage and next generation renewables.
5. Higher mandatory energy efciency standards for all
new buildings.
6. Scrappage schemes
7. Investment in climate adaptation and resilience.
8. Public awareness campaigns to promote dietary
changes that both reduce emissions and improve
health.
9. Lowering the voting age to 16.
111
Content
Title Authors
Pub -
lished
Key Questions
Theories, Models,
Methods
Recommendations
Useful Insights and
Arguments
The Economy For the Common
Good
Christian Felber, Gus
Hagelberg
2017 How to build an economy for the common
good?
ECG Frameworks Ethical market economy designed to increase quality of
life for all
Promote values of human dignity, human rights,
ecological responsibility
Need for Common Good balance Sheet
Common Good companies benet in marketplace
through consumer choice, cooperation partners,
common-good-orientated lending institutions
Common Good companies should benet from
advantages in taxation, bank loans and public grants and
contracts
Biz prots serve to strengthen and stabilize a company
and to ensure the income of owners and employees over
the long term
Companies no longer forced to expand and grow
Reduce income inequality is mandatory in order
to assure everyone equal economic and political
opportunities
Future Fit Positive Pursuit
Guide
2020 What can businesses do above and beyond its
pursuit to break-even to speed up transition
to future-tness?
Future Fit
Frameworks
Create positive impact
Reduce negative impact
Amplify the positive impact of others
Ökonomien der Transformation
– Ansätze zukunftsfähigen
Wirtschaftens
WWF Deutschland 2020 Describes and criticizes concepts of Green
Economy, Bio Economy, Circular Economy
and checks practical examples of sustainable
development.
Best Practices Moves away from the absolute growth paradigm and
establishes thinking in a holistic and sustainable way.
World Bank (2020) Proposed
Sustainability Checklist for
Assessing Economic Recovery
Interventions, April 2020
World Bank Group -
Climate Change
2020 What are the steps to be taken for assessing
the sustainability of economic recovery
interventions?
Checklist divided
by topic and
short-term/
long-term
Aspects for assessing sustainability of economic recovery
interventions:
Impacts on employment
Economic activity
Timeliness and risk
Impact on human, social, natural, cultural and physical
capital impact on technologies
Impact on fundamental market failures, increase
resilience and adaptive capacity
Decarbonisationation
Addresses market failures and
impacts on different forms of
capital, including natural and
cultural in economic recovery
interventions post COVID-19
crisis.
COP26 Universities Network
Brieng (April 2020) A net-zero
emissions economic recovery
from COVID-19
COP26 Universities
Network (Jennifer Allan
et al.)
2020 How can the transition to net-zero emissions
contribute to recovery and economic growth
after covid19?
Policy survey Reduce emissions
Invest in cleaner technology/research/infrastructures,
invest in nature-based solutions
Establish a Sustainable Recovery Alliance at COP26
UK could lead a climate-safe
recovery from COVID-19 by
leading a Sustainable Recovery
Alliance at COP26
Evergreen Action Plan
Sam Ricketts, Bracken
Hendricks and Maggie
Thomas
2020 How can we contribute to defeating the
climate crisis and build a new, socially and
environmentally sustainable economy?
n. a. Invest in green and socially inclusive economic progress,
especially regarding job creation
Use foreign policy to promote global action against
climate change
National and international
mobilization is key.
Envisioning a Not-For-Prot
World for a Sustainable Future
Jennifer Hinton 2019 How can we contribute to a Not-For-Prot
Business model for a sustainable economy?
Change directive for businesses to move beyond making
money.
Prot is not an end goal in itself.
Prot is only a means to create
a deeper end, community benet.
Committee on Climate Change
(2020) Letter to Prime Minister
on COVID19 recovery
Committee on Climate
Change (Lord Deben,
Baroness Brown of
Cambridge), Helen
Brown, Saamah
Abdallah, Ruth Townsley
2020 How can actions towards net-zero emissions
and to limit the damages from climate
change help rebuild the UK with a stronger
economy and increased resilience? How can
governments use local wellbeing indicators to
inform policy making?
Prioritisation of
actions based on
six principles of
resilient recovery.
Happy City Index,
1. Use climate investments to support the economic
recovery and jobs.
2. Lead a shift towards positive long-term behaviours.
3. Tackle the wider “resilience decit” on climate change.
4. Embed fairness as a core principle.
5. Ensure the recovery does not “lock-in” greenhouse gas
emissions or increased climate risk.
6. Strengthen incentives to reduce emissions when
considering scal changes.
7. “Measure what matters”.
Investments in low-carbon and
climate-resilient infrastructure
Support reskilling, retraining
and research for a net-zero,
well-adapted economy
Upgrades to buildings
Facilitation of walk, cycle, and
work remotely
Tree planting, peatland
restoration, green spaces and
other green infrastructure
Content
112
Title Authors
Pub -
lished
Key Questions
Theories, Models,
Methods
Recommendations
Useful Insights and
Arguments
The Economy For the Common
Good
Christian Felber, Gus
Hagelberg
2017 How to build an economy for the common
good?
ECG Frameworks Ethical market economy designed to increase quality of
life for all
Promote values of human dignity, human rights,
ecological responsibility
Need for Common Good balance Sheet
Common Good companies benet in marketplace
through consumer choice, cooperation partners,
common-good-orientated lending institutions
Common Good companies should benet from
advantages in taxation, bank loans and public grants and
contracts
Biz prots serve to strengthen and stabilize a company
and to ensure the income of owners and employees over
the long term
Companies no longer forced to expand and grow
Reduce income inequality is mandatory in order
to assure everyone equal economic and political
opportunities
Future Fit Positive Pursuit
Guide
2020 What can businesses do above and beyond its
pursuit to break-even to speed up transition
to future-tness?
Future Fit
Frameworks
Create positive impact
Reduce negative impact
Amplify the positive impact of others
Ökonomien der Transformation
– Ansätze zukunftsfähigen
Wirtschaftens
WWF Deutschland 2020 Describes and criticizes concepts of Green
Economy, Bio Economy, Circular Economy
and checks practical examples of sustainable
development.
Best Practices Moves away from the absolute growth paradigm and
establishes thinking in a holistic and sustainable way.
World Bank (2020) Proposed
Sustainability Checklist for
Assessing Economic Recovery
Interventions, April 2020
World Bank Group -
Climate Change
2020 What are the steps to be taken for assessing
the sustainability of economic recovery
interventions?
Checklist divided
by topic and
short-term/
long-term
Aspects for assessing sustainability of economic recovery
interventions:
Impacts on employment
Economic activity
Timeliness and risk
Impact on human, social, natural, cultural and physical
capital impact on technologies
Impact on fundamental market failures, increase
resilience and adaptive capacity
Decarbonisationation
Addresses market failures and
impacts on different forms of
capital, including natural and
cultural in economic recovery
interventions post COVID-19
crisis.
COP26 Universities Network
Brieng (April 2020) A net-zero
emissions economic recovery
from COVID-19
COP26 Universities
Network (Jennifer Allan
et al.)
2020 How can the transition to net-zero emissions
contribute to recovery and economic growth
after covid19?
Policy survey Reduce emissions
Invest in cleaner technology/research/infrastructures,
invest in nature-based solutions
Establish a Sustainable Recovery Alliance at COP26
UK could lead a climate-safe
recovery from COVID-19 by
leading a Sustainable Recovery
Alliance at COP26
Evergreen Action Plan
Sam Ricketts, Bracken
Hendricks and Maggie
Thomas
2020 How can we contribute to defeating the
climate crisis and build a new, socially and
environmentally sustainable economy?
n. a. Invest in green and socially inclusive economic progress,
especially regarding job creation
Use foreign policy to promote global action against
climate change
National and international
mobilization is key.
Envisioning a Not-For-Prot
World for a Sustainable Future
Jennifer Hinton 2019 How can we contribute to a Not-For-Prot
Business model for a sustainable economy?
Change directive for businesses to move beyond making
money.
Prot is not an end goal in itself.
Prot is only a means to create
a deeper end, community benet.
Committee on Climate Change
(2020) Letter to Prime Minister
on COVID19 recovery
Committee on Climate
Change (Lord Deben,
Baroness Brown of
Cambridge), Helen
Brown, Saamah
Abdallah, Ruth Townsley
2020 How can actions towards net-zero emissions
and to limit the damages from climate
change help rebuild the UK with a stronger
economy and increased resilience? How can
governments use local wellbeing indicators to
inform policy making?
Prioritisation of
actions based on
six principles of
resilient recovery.
Happy City Index,
1. Use climate investments to support the economic
recovery and jobs.
2. Lead a shift towards positive long-term behaviours.
3. Tackle the wider “resilience decit” on climate change.
4. Embed fairness as a core principle.
5. Ensure the recovery does not “lock-in” greenhouse gas
emissions or increased climate risk.
6. Strengthen incentives to reduce emissions when
considering scal changes.
7. “Measure what matters”.
Investments in low-carbon and
climate-resilient infrastructure
Support reskilling, retraining
and research for a net-zero,
well-adapted economy
Upgrades to buildings
Facilitation of walk, cycle, and
work remotely
Tree planting, peatland
restoration, green spaces and
other green infrastructure
113
Content
Title Authors
Pub -
lished
Key Questions
Theories, Models,
Methods
Recommendations
Useful Insights and
Arguments
September 2020 (and March
2021): the temporary and
the permanent impacts of
coronavirus, Dieter Helm, 25th
March 2020
Dieter Helm 2020 What will be the temporary and more
importantly the permanent effects once the
immediate emergency is over?
Qualitative scenario Support to health service
Measures of prevention and resilience to mitigate effects
of future pandemics and impacts from environmental
destruction
COVID-19 crisis will accelerate
renationalisation, intergenera-
tional conflicts and the retreat
from globalisation.
Why We Need a National
Investment Authority
Saule T. Omarova 2020 How can the US federal government mobilize
economic resources and manage emergency
bailouts in response to systemic crises in a
fully national, well-coordinated manner?
Set-up of a “national investment authority, responsible
for:
1. Monitoring and management of capital allocation
2. Formulation of rapid crisis response/emergency bailout
mechanisms
3. Implementation of long-term economic development
strategies on the federal level
US Treasury and FED’s lack of
transparency and accountability
can equally be applied to the
European Central Bank.
MDBs (multilateral devel-
opment banks) response to
COVID19
Chris Humphrey (ODI) 2020 How to scale up multilateral nancing to face
the COVID-19 crisis?
Bond rating
Financial
investment for
development
Essential to expand lending to developing countries in a
coordinated manner among the major MDBs, with explicit
support of G20 and other shareholders.
MDB lending is crucial for
developing countries to recover
from COVID-19.
Jackson, Tim. 2017. Prosperity
without growth: foundations
for the economy of tomorrow
Tim Jackson 2017 What can prosperity possibly look like in a
nite world, with limited resources and a
population expected to exceed ten billion
people within a few decades? How is a new
understanding of prosperity made possible in
world that is not relying on economic growth?
Become
independent of
growth
Redene
prosperity
Re-dene:
a. enterprises
b. work
c. investment
d. money
e. the role of the State
CAN INTERNATIONAL (2020):
Fundamentals for Recovery &
Economic Stimulus Packages
in response to COVID-19, May
2020
Climate Action Network
International (CAN)
2020 What are the short- and long-term measures
to be implemented by governments
and all stakeholders to respond to this
pandemic and incoming climate related
challenges?
Not bail out dirty industries.
Planning and investments shall meet environmental and
social standards.
Equity should be at the hearth of policy responses to
crisis.
End fossil fuel subsidies.
Resilience depends on equity.
A government roadmap for
addressing the climate and
post COVID-19 economic
crises
Climate Action Tracker 2020 How can we synergistically solve COVID-19
and climate change crisis?
Scenario modelling
and projections
Green economic recovery would solve COVID-19 and the
climate crisis if certain actions are taken and some are
avoided.
Trade-offs and synergies
between COVID-19 and climate
change.
Post-Growth Policy
Instruments
Peter Ferguson 2013 Framework to evaluate post-growth policy.
Most effective policies reduce average
working hours, expand low productivity
sectors and reduce inequality. Specic
policy instruments include public sector
expansion and the promotion of cooperatives,
the introduction of citizens’ basic income
schemes, environmental tax reform, the
abolition of fossil fuel subsidies, reforms to
monetary policy, nancial regulatory reform
and the introduction of alternative measures
of progress to gross domestic product.
Wellbeing Budget New Zealand
New Zealand
Government
2020 What is the New Zealand government doing to
build a wellbeing economy?
Policy measures $ 3 B in operating funding/year
to ensure government services
continue to support NZ people
through extraordinary time.
Expand low productivity sectors
and reduce inequality.
Designing Border Carbon
Adjustments for Enhanced
Climate Action
Michael A. Mehling,
Harro van Asselt, Kasturi
Das, Susanne Droege,
Cleo Verkuijl
2019 How to design border carbon adjustments in
conformity with international trade law?
Historical overview
and policy analysis
Design and implement BCAs as to conform to international
trade law and WTO rules.
Illustration of the legal uncertain-
ties of GATT prescription when
designing BCAs.
Content
114
Title Authors
Pub -
lished
Key Questions
Theories, Models,
Methods
Recommendations
Useful Insights and
Arguments
September 2020 (and March
2021): the temporary and
the permanent impacts of
coronavirus, Dieter Helm, 25th
March 2020
Dieter Helm 2020 What will be the temporary and more
importantly the permanent effects once the
immediate emergency is over?
Qualitative scenario Support to health service
Measures of prevention and resilience to mitigate effects
of future pandemics and impacts from environmental
destruction
COVID-19 crisis will accelerate
renationalisation, intergenera-
tional conflicts and the retreat
from globalisation.
Why We Need a National
Investment Authority
Saule T. Omarova 2020 How can the US federal government mobilize
economic resources and manage emergency
bailouts in response to systemic crises in a
fully national, well-coordinated manner?
Set-up of a “national investment authority, responsible
for:
1. Monitoring and management of capital allocation
2. Formulation of rapid crisis response/emergency bailout
mechanisms
3. Implementation of long-term economic development
strategies on the federal level
US Treasury and FED’s lack of
transparency and accountability
can equally be applied to the
European Central Bank.
MDBs (multilateral devel-
opment banks) response to
COVID19
Chris Humphrey (ODI) 2020 How to scale up multilateral nancing to face
the COVID-19 crisis?
Bond rating
Financial
investment for
development
Essential to expand lending to developing countries in a
coordinated manner among the major MDBs, with explicit
support of G20 and other shareholders.
MDB lending is crucial for
developing countries to recover
from COVID-19.
Jackson, Tim. 2017. Prosperity
without growth: foundations
for the economy of tomorrow
Tim Jackson 2017 What can prosperity possibly look like in a
nite world, with limited resources and a
population expected to exceed ten billion
people within a few decades? How is a new
understanding of prosperity made possible in
world that is not relying on economic growth?
Become
independent of
growth
Redene
prosperity
Re-dene:
a. enterprises
b. work
c. investment
d. money
e. the role of the State
CAN INTERNATIONAL (2020):
Fundamentals for Recovery &
Economic Stimulus Packages
in response to COVID-19, May
2020
Climate Action Network
International (CAN)
2020 What are the short- and long-term measures
to be implemented by governments
and all stakeholders to respond to this
pandemic and incoming climate related
challenges?
Not bail out dirty industries.
Planning and investments shall meet environmental and
social standards.
Equity should be at the hearth of policy responses to
crisis.
End fossil fuel subsidies.
Resilience depends on equity.
A government roadmap for
addressing the climate and
post COVID-19 economic
crises
Climate Action Tracker 2020 How can we synergistically solve COVID-19
and climate change crisis?
Scenario modelling
and projections
Green economic recovery would solve COVID-19 and the
climate crisis if certain actions are taken and some are
avoided.
Trade-offs and synergies
between COVID-19 and climate
change.
Post-Growth Policy
Instruments
Peter Ferguson 2013 Framework to evaluate post-growth policy.
Most effective policies reduce average
working hours, expand low productivity
sectors and reduce inequality. Specic
policy instruments include public sector
expansion and the promotion of cooperatives,
the introduction of citizens’ basic income
schemes, environmental tax reform, the
abolition of fossil fuel subsidies, reforms to
monetary policy, nancial regulatory reform
and the introduction of alternative measures
of progress to gross domestic product.
Wellbeing Budget New Zealand
New Zealand
Government
2020 What is the New Zealand government doing to
build a wellbeing economy?
Policy measures $ 3 B in operating funding/year
to ensure government services
continue to support NZ people
through extraordinary time.
Expand low productivity sectors
and reduce inequality.
Designing Border Carbon
Adjustments for Enhanced
Climate Action
Michael A. Mehling,
Harro van Asselt, Kasturi
Das, Susanne Droege,
Cleo Verkuijl
2019 How to design border carbon adjustments in
conformity with international trade law?
Historical overview
and policy analysis
Design and implement BCAs as to conform to international
trade law and WTO rules.
Illustration of the legal uncertain-
ties of GATT prescription when
designing BCAs.
115
Content
Title Authors
Pub -
lished
Key Questions
Theories, Models,
Methods
Recommendations
Useful Insights and
Arguments
Gesellschaftliches Wohl-
ergehen innerhalb planetarer
Grenzen – Der Ansatz
einer vorsorgeorientierten
Postwachstumsposition
Umweltbundesamt 2018 What is the role of economic performance
(growth) and its future development in
maintaining planetary boundaries? What are
the best policies that degrowth and degrowth
could possibly deliver? How would the
perspective of a “precautionary post-growth
position” look like?
Policies from
degrowth and green
growth perspective
Instruments to achieve environmental objectives and
to reduce the dependence on growth in the area of
employment and social security systems
The Green Swan: Central
Banking in the Age of Climate
Change
Patrick Bolton, Morgan
Despres, Luiz Awazu
Pereira da Silva, Frederic
Samana, Romain
Svartzman
2020 What is the role for central banks in the
complex, non-linear affair of climate change?
Which actions can they take within their
mandates?
Non-equilibrium
models (e. g. Stock
flow consistent,
Agent based).
Sensitivity analysis,
Case studies on risks
and transmission
channels between
climate change,
ecological transition,
real economy and
nancial stability.
Socio-technical
systems change
model (Geels et al.
2017)
Integrate climate-related risks into macroprudential
supervision through stress testing and micro-supervision
of nancial institutions strategies and risk management
procedures. Use Central Banks’ own portfolios to promote
green (extra-nancial) objectives. Update collateral
frameworks for Quantitative Easing to reflect climate-
related risks – thus abandoning a false notion of “neutral-
ity. Cooperate with governments and scal policy for
nancing a transition. Engage in multilateral cooperation.
Integrate sustainability into corporate and national
accounting frameworks
Comprehension of climate-
related risks need to go beyond
established policy and modelling
practices.
Network for Greening the
Financial System: A call for
action Climate change as a
source of nancial risk
Network For Greening
the Financial System
(63 central banks and
supervisors). Secretariat
is provided by the
Banque de France
2019 Understanding how climate change affects
the nancial system and the economy.
Scenario analysis,
granular modelling
of transmission
channels. Critical
stance towards
integrated assess-
ment models
1. Integrate climate-related risks to prudential
supervision.
2. Manage own portfolios according to sustainability
criteria.
3. Bridge data gaps.
4. Build awareness and institutional capacity.
5. Achieve robust and internationally standardised
disclosures.
6. Support the development of a taxonomy for economic
activities.
Focus on scenarios and trans-
mission channels instead of
macro modelling.
Growth imperatives:
Substantiating a contested
concept
Oliver Richters, Andreas
Siemoneit
2019 Economic growth remains a prominent polit-
ical goal, despite its conflicts with ecological
sustainability. Are growth policies only a
question of political or individual will, or do
growth imperatives” make the inescapable?
Literature review Limit resource consumption and redistribute economic
rents.
Integrating Climate-related
Risks into Banks’ Capital
Requirements
Maria Berenguer, Michel
Cardona, Julie Evain
2020 Unpack the debate about using differentials
in capital requirements to green the nancial
system.
Development of a taxonomy
Being explicit about which goal (reduction of risk or
industrial policy) one wants to achieve
Debate about capital
requirements
The UK: Global Hub, Local
Dynamics: Mapping the
Transition to a Sustainable
Financial System
Nick Robins and Jeremy
McDaniels
2016 Describe developments in sustainable nance
in the UK and make recommendations for a
strategy.
Ecosystem mapping
exercise through
case study
Social Innovation: aligning nance with individual values
and social purpose, from socially responsible investment
through fossil fuel divestment to new green peer-to-peer
initiatives.
Institutional Stewardship: placing sustainability factors at
the heart of mainstream nancial sectors, most notably
investment management.
Housing Finance: improving the environmental and energy
performance of the UK’s housing stock through new ways
to mobilize nancing.
Capital Markets Mobilization: incorporating sustainability
into equity and debt market disclosure, analysis and
capital raising.
Prudential Governance: embedding sustainability into the
oversight of the safety and soundness of key sectors and
the system as a whole.
Public Balance Sheet: mobilizing scal and other resources
to facilitate the transition to a low-carbon, green economy.
Content
116
Title Authors
Pub -
lished
Key Questions
Theories, Models,
Methods
Recommendations
Useful Insights and
Arguments
Gesellschaftliches Wohl-
ergehen innerhalb planetarer
Grenzen – Der Ansatz
einer vorsorgeorientierten
Postwachstumsposition
Umweltbundesamt 2018 What is the role of economic performance
(growth) and its future development in
maintaining planetary boundaries? What are
the best policies that degrowth and degrowth
could possibly deliver? How would the
perspective of a “precautionary post-growth
position” look like?
Policies from
degrowth and green
growth perspective
Instruments to achieve environmental objectives and
to reduce the dependence on growth in the area of
employment and social security systems
The Green Swan: Central
Banking in the Age of Climate
Change
Patrick Bolton, Morgan
Despres, Luiz Awazu
Pereira da Silva, Frederic
Samana, Romain
Svartzman
2020 What is the role for central banks in the
complex, non-linear affair of climate change?
Which actions can they take within their
mandates?
Non-equilibrium
models (e. g. Stock
flow consistent,
Agent based).
Sensitivity analysis,
Case studies on risks
and transmission
channels between
climate change,
ecological transition,
real economy and
nancial stability.
Socio-technical
systems change
model (Geels et al.
2017)
Integrate climate-related risks into macroprudential
supervision through stress testing and micro-supervision
of nancial institutions strategies and risk management
procedures. Use Central Banks’ own portfolios to promote
green (extra-nancial) objectives. Update collateral
frameworks for Quantitative Easing to reflect climate-
related risks – thus abandoning a false notion of “neutral-
ity. Cooperate with governments and scal policy for
nancing a transition. Engage in multilateral cooperation.
Integrate sustainability into corporate and national
accounting frameworks
Comprehension of climate-
related risks need to go beyond
established policy and modelling
practices.
Network for Greening the
Financial System: A call for
action Climate change as a
source of nancial risk
Network For Greening
the Financial System
(63 central banks and
supervisors). Secretariat
is provided by the
Banque de France
2019 Understanding how climate change affects
the nancial system and the economy.
Scenario analysis,
granular modelling
of transmission
channels. Critical
stance towards
integrated assess-
ment models
1. Integrate climate-related risks to prudential
supervision.
2. Manage own portfolios according to sustainability
criteria.
3. Bridge data gaps.
4. Build awareness and institutional capacity.
5. Achieve robust and internationally standardised
disclosures.
6. Support the development of a taxonomy for economic
activities.
Focus on scenarios and trans-
mission channels instead of
macro modelling.
Growth imperatives:
Substantiating a contested
concept
Oliver Richters, Andreas
Siemoneit
2019 Economic growth remains a prominent polit-
ical goal, despite its conflicts with ecological
sustainability. Are growth policies only a
question of political or individual will, or do
growth imperatives” make the inescapable?
Literature review Limit resource consumption and redistribute economic
rents.
Integrating Climate-related
Risks into Banks’ Capital
Requirements
Maria Berenguer, Michel
Cardona, Julie Evain
2020 Unpack the debate about using differentials
in capital requirements to green the nancial
system.
Development of a taxonomy
Being explicit about which goal (reduction of risk or
industrial policy) one wants to achieve
Debate about capital
requirements
The UK: Global Hub, Local
Dynamics: Mapping the
Transition to a Sustainable
Financial System
Nick Robins and Jeremy
McDaniels
2016 Describe developments in sustainable nance
in the UK and make recommendations for a
strategy.
Ecosystem mapping
exercise through
case study
Social Innovation: aligning nance with individual values
and social purpose, from socially responsible investment
through fossil fuel divestment to new green peer-to-peer
initiatives.
Institutional Stewardship: placing sustainability factors at
the heart of mainstream nancial sectors, most notably
investment management.
Housing Finance: improving the environmental and energy
performance of the UK’s housing stock through new ways
to mobilize nancing.
Capital Markets Mobilization: incorporating sustainability
into equity and debt market disclosure, analysis and
capital raising.
Prudential Governance: embedding sustainability into the
oversight of the safety and soundness of key sectors and
the system as a whole.
Public Balance Sheet: mobilizing scal and other resources
to facilitate the transition to a low-carbon, green economy.
117
Content
Title Authors
Pub -
lished
Key Questions
Theories, Models,
Methods
Recommendations
Useful Insights and
Arguments
Greening Monetary Policy
Dirk Schoenmaker 2019 Should Central Banks take the carbon
intensity of
assets into account in the context of mone-
tary policy?
Legal argument for
the ECB, numerical
examples for green
tilting.
Green tilt of central banks’ corporate bond portfolio. Proposes an incremental green
quantitative easing path that
might be easier to implement
than full scale suggestions.
OECD Green Budgeting
2020
Standardise accounting Green budgeting
Into the wild – Integrating
nature into investment
strategies
Hugo Bluet, Ciprian
Ionescu,
2019 How can nance contribute to the decrease of
the degradation of biodiversity?
Case studies,
revisiting of
biodiversity and
other ecosystem
foot-printing and
scenario tools
1. Task force on nature related disclosures in analogy to
FSB TCFD
2. Ensure that biodiversity is integrated in ESG ratings – in
the longer-term methodologies should be harmonized
3. Develop a framework to assess biodiversity risk.
4. Develop biodiversity labels for nancial products
State of the Apes The Impact
of Infrastructure Development
on Biodiversity
Jo Alexander 2019 What should institutional investors do to mini-
mize harmful impacts on biodiversity when
investing in infrastructure projects? What
risks does the failure to consider biodiversity
questions entail?
Investors and banks should establish processes to monitor
biodiversity as well as dispossession of indigenous land
when nancing infrastructure projects.
A Green Stimulus to Rebuild
Our Economy;
Johanna Bozuwa et al. 2020 What kind of economic stimulus should we
pursue to respond to COVID-19, climate
change and rising inequality in the US?
Policy option menu
grounded on four
key strategies
Create new family-sustaining, career-track green jobs
Deliver strategic investments
Expand public and employee ownership
Make rapid cuts to carbon pollution
Climate change is a challenge
but also presents opportunities
for ghting unemployment and
inequality.
Issues in the design of scal
policy rules
Portes and Wren-Lewis 2014 Repositioning scal rules as enablers of
government spending to aid resilience and
solve social and environmental issues rather
than merely maintaining stable debt-to-GDP
ratios.
Fiscal rules that target necessary decit
“Fiscal councils” to help guard against either under or
overuse of scal space
Just about managing demand:
Reforming the UK’s macro-
economic policy framework
Ale Stirling 2018 1. New scal rules which would enable more
active scal policy in a downturn, including
greater public investment.
2. Revision of the Bank of England’s mandate
to help interest rates rise faster in time for
the next recession.
3. New mechanism to delegate an economic
stimulus to a new National Investment
Bank and purchase its bonds to ensure a
direct injection of demand.
Demand.
Public Finance for a Green New
Deal
Stirling and van Lerven 2019 What kind of scal rules and policy framework
(macroeconomics) do we need to tackle the
climate emergency?
New scal rules and coordination between treasury and
central banks
Government borrowing is key
to tackle climate and wider
ecological crisis
Content
118
Title Authors
Pub -
lished
Key Questions
Theories, Models,
Methods
Recommendations
Useful Insights and
Arguments
Greening Monetary Policy
Dirk Schoenmaker 2019 Should Central Banks take the carbon
intensity of
assets into account in the context of mone-
tary policy?
Legal argument for
the ECB, numerical
examples for green
tilting.
Green tilt of central banks’ corporate bond portfolio. Proposes an incremental green
quantitative easing path that
might be easier to implement
than full scale suggestions.
OECD Green Budgeting
2020
Standardise accounting Green budgeting
Into the wild – Integrating
nature into investment
strategies
Hugo Bluet, Ciprian
Ionescu,
2019 How can nance contribute to the decrease of
the degradation of biodiversity?
Case studies,
revisiting of
biodiversity and
other ecosystem
foot-printing and
scenario tools
1. Task force on nature related disclosures in analogy to
FSB TCFD
2. Ensure that biodiversity is integrated in ESG ratings – in
the longer-term methodologies should be harmonized
3. Develop a framework to assess biodiversity risk.
4. Develop biodiversity labels for nancial products
State of the Apes The Impact
of Infrastructure Development
on Biodiversity
Jo Alexander 2019 What should institutional investors do to mini-
mize harmful impacts on biodiversity when
investing in infrastructure projects? What
risks does the failure to consider biodiversity
questions entail?
Investors and banks should establish processes to monitor
biodiversity as well as dispossession of indigenous land
when nancing infrastructure projects.
A Green Stimulus to Rebuild
Our Economy;
Johanna Bozuwa et al. 2020 What kind of economic stimulus should we
pursue to respond to COVID-19, climate
change and rising inequality in the US?
Policy option menu
grounded on four
key strategies
Create new family-sustaining, career-track green jobs
Deliver strategic investments
Expand public and employee ownership
Make rapid cuts to carbon pollution
Climate change is a challenge
but also presents opportunities
for ghting unemployment and
inequality.
Issues in the design of scal
policy rules
Portes and Wren-Lewis 2014 Repositioning scal rules as enablers of
government spending to aid resilience and
solve social and environmental issues rather
than merely maintaining stable debt-to-GDP
ratios.
Fiscal rules that target necessary decit
“Fiscal councils” to help guard against either under or
overuse of scal space
Just about managing demand:
Reforming the UK’s macro-
economic policy framework
Ale Stirling 2018 1. New scal rules which would enable more
active scal policy in a downturn, including
greater public investment.
2. Revision of the Bank of England’s mandate
to help interest rates rise faster in time for
the next recession.
3. New mechanism to delegate an economic
stimulus to a new National Investment
Bank and purchase its bonds to ensure a
direct injection of demand.
Demand.
Public Finance for a Green New
Deal
Stirling and van Lerven 2019 What kind of scal rules and policy framework
(macroeconomics) do we need to tackle the
climate emergency?
New scal rules and coordination between treasury and
central banks
Government borrowing is key
to tackle climate and wider
ecological crisis
119
Content
Page intentionally left blank.
ZOE. institute for future-t economies
Thomas Mann Str. 36, 53111 Bonn, Germany
+49 (0) 228 / 387 576 02 — info@zoe-institut.de
www.zoe-institut.de/en
institute for
future-fit
economies